SPIKED
SCIENCE
October 23 2002
Patent problems
by Sandy Starr
Patents
- which give individuals or organisations an exclusive right, for
a limited period of time, to profit from inventions - have come in
for some bad press recently.
In the age of genetic manipulation and computer technology, ethical
questions are often raised about what we should be allowed to patent,
and how patents should be applied to the developing world.
What
is more surprising is that patents are being given a hard time by
those who use them. An increasing number of individual inventors believe
that the patent system works against them rather than for them, while
the companies who deal in patented innovations increasingly see patents
as being fraught with risk and danger.
Such
concerns were raised at 'Intellectual Property Enforcement', a discussion
organised by Ideas 21 and held at the UK Patent Office in London in
September 2002 (1). The event was chaired by Michael Fysh, judge of
the Patents County Court. He gave an anecdote to illustrate the complexities
of the present patent system - telling us how a recent patent application
for a simple device, 'a collar for holding a pipe', met with radically
different judgements from eight different courts in three European
countries. When such diverse judgements are possible, patent disputes
become costly and difficult.
Fair
enough, you might say - granting patents has never been easy. After
all, there is much debate as to what constitutes a new invention,
as distinct from the mere reproduction of, or improvement upon, existing
ideas and processes. As technology advances, precisely defining inventions
becomes more difficult. Yet the attitude to patents adopted by business
today seems to go beyond the specific difficulties of patenting, and
reveals much about today's business climate.
Sam
Bobo, underwriter and company secretary at the Miller Insurance Group
(2), urged us to see 'risk management as part of litigation' when
it comes to patents. He advised taking out insurance to cover possible
losses incurred in patent disputes, arguing that just owning such
insurance is a deterrent against patent infringement.
Judge
Fysh said that when he began his career in law, such insurance was
unheard of - even though risk has always been an important consideration
with patents. Any invention you invest in runs the risk of failing
to be granted a patent. And even if an invention is patented, it runs
the risk of failing in the marketplace. But such risk has traditionally
been seen as inherent to business and invention, rather than needing
to be considered in its own special terms.
Patents
used to be seen by businesses as a mechanism for securing new profits
through exclusive licensing. But today, patents are seen either as
a mechanism for scaring competitors, or as a liability, because of
the possibility that they might be infringed and cost a lot in subsequent
litigation.
The
patent system can be used in just as cynical a fashion as it can be
infringed
When patents are seen more as a liability than an opportunity,
drastic steps are taken to protect them. Conrad Arnander, partner
with the law firm Shook, Hardy and Bacon (3), advocated the creation
of 'a heavily built wall of other rights around your patent'. His
'other rights' included international patenting (in those countries
where patents are most easily obtained); explicitly defining new innovation
as improvement upon already patented inventions; yoking your patent
to other forms of intellectual property; and building a strong brand
around your patented inventions.
You
can't help wondering whether all this desperate activity to protect
patents does anything to assist the activity that patents are intended
to stimulate - innovation. As the UK's Commission on Intellectual
Property Rights (4) points out, intellectual property rights are 'instruments
of public policy which confer economic privileges on individuals or
institutions solely for the purposes of contributing to the greater
public good. The privilege is therefore a means to an end, not an
end in itself' (5).
Admittedly,
there are those who argue that a risk management mentality does in
fact aid innovation, on the grounds that when risks are minimised
and clearly defined, businesses have a greater incentive to invest,
and inventors have a greater incentive to innovate. William Kingston,
a prominent advocate of patent reform, argues that 'if all inputs
and outputs could be measured accurately, then the logic of a grant
of protection would have it last until an investor in research and
development had received a multiple of the investment made which exactly
corresponded to the risk which was taken in making it' (6).
But
in reality, such awareness and redistribution of risk often leads
to inaction. The key word in Kingston's assertion is 'if'. To the
extent that the caprices of the marketplace are knowable, they are
a distraction from the kind of innovation you need to focus on in
order to achieve breakthrough and consequent success. Risk management
may make it safer to do business around innovation, but it will not
stimulate innovation, and is therefore ultimately self-defeating.
Some
people claim that risk management is necessary because of the increase
in patent infringement. At 'Intellectual Property Enforcement', John
Reid, chair of the Intellectual Property Awareness Group, called for
an 'expectation that valid patents will be rewarded', and argued that
there is at present too much 'cynical infringement' of patents.
This
may be true, but the patent system can be used in just as cynical
a fashion as it can be infringed - by businesses desperate to wring
value from every asset that they have, attempting to either patent
or associate with an existing patent every incremental development
in their work. The patent system has not been revved up to counter
a sudden rash of infringements. Rather, legitimate use and illegitimate
infringement of patents alike reflect the business culture.
Ironically,
although risk management is bound up with a heightened sensitivity
towards competition, the urge to redistribute risk actually undermines
competition, as equally nervous firms band together and batten down
the hatches. The inventor John Mitchell, managing director of AllVoice
Computing plc (7), told the audience at 'Intellectual Property Enforcement'
about the urgent need to 'cure the loss of intellectual property'.
He cited a recent European Commission funded report, in which William
Kingston proposed the creation of a 'Patent Defence Union' - 'an EU-wide
voluntary grouping of SME patentees to defend their patents' (8).
This
safety-in-numbers mentality is also expressed in the phenomenon of
cross-licensing, in which businesses share the licences for their
patented inventions with other businesses. Here, again, patents cease
to be a spur to innovation, and become a bargaining chip between the
cautious.
Patents have become a bargaining chip between the cautious
Cross-licensing has unfortunate consequences for innovation. Intellectual
property seeks to strike a balance between providing an incentive
to innovate, and allowing for the fair use of innovations by the public.
This balance is predicated upon the exclusivity of the rights conferred
upon the innovator.
Once
this exclusivity is removed, in the case of patents, there is less
incentive to take risks with new innovations, while a coterie of businesses
maximises the profit from existing innovations. In the words of the
Commission on Intellectual Property Rights, 'essentially, non-exclusive
licensing is a tax on users of technology' (9).
One
aspect of patents that is even less popular than their exclusivity
is their provisional character. Intellectual property law allows a
patent to be disqualified even after it has been granted - for example,
if there is new evidence that the patented invention was not new at
the time that it was patented. At 'Intellectual Property Enforcement',
inventor Heather Davies, director of the packaging products company
Reuzip (10), was furious that patents carry no guarantee of validity
once obtained. She argued that obtaining a patent should be like buying
a product - there should be a guarantee of sale.
Judge
Fysh replied that 'no patent office in the world has ever guaranteed
the validity of a patent', and explained that no matter how extensively
a patent office searches for 'prior use' of an invention, it is always
possible that an incidence of prior use will be discovered. John Mitchell
was unimpressed, asking: 'If you can never guarantee it, how can you
make a judgement on it?' Mitchell proposed that there should be only
a limited period of time during which new patent claims can be challenged,
after which the patent should be immune to the discovery of prior
use.
Such
a regime would shift the burden of responsibility in patents, so that
instead of it being incumbent upon patentees to establish the novelty
of their invention, it would be incumbent upon all inventors to protect
their inventions from would-be patentees. The consequence would be
to make patents an automatic reward for wanting to bring an innovation
to market, rather than an incentive to bring innovations into the
public domain that do not exist there at present.
It
is difficult to establish with precision whether recent changes, in
the way that patents are used and understood, have had an adverse
effect upon innovation. The Commission on Intellectual Property Rights
points out that 'we cannot measure directly a country's capacity for
innovation.... Nor can we directly measure the strength of patent
protection in a country.' (11) Nonetheless, the Commission does present
some disquieting statistics:
'In
the USA, and to a lesser extent worldwide, the number of patents granted
has been rapidly rising. Between 1981 and 2000, the number of patents
granted in the USA has increased from 71,000 to over 184,000, an increase
of 159 percent. In the last five years the rise has accelerated, the
number of patents granted has increased by over 50 percent, compared
to an increase of under 14 percent in the previous five years. This
increase appears to reflect growth in the intensity of patenting...rather
than a 50 percent increase in the number of inventions.' (12)
Growth
in the 'intensity of patenting' without corresponding growth in innovation
leads to the problem of patent dilution - patents become less valuable,
in both social and economic terms. The solution to this problem does
not lie in reforming the patent system, even if there is a legitimate
case to be made for greater stringency in granting patents. Indeed,
many of today's proposals for patent reform would most likely work
against, rather than for, innovation, because they wrongly assume
that the problem lies with the mechanism of the patent.
Intellectual
property is a contrived means of encouraging innovation within the
marketplace. At best, it will always be, to some extent, imperfect,
imprecise and arbitrary. The real question facing us is whether we
want to use the existence of intellectual property as a platform for
long-term innovation, or whether we want to use it as a crutch for
short-term security.
Issued:
23 October 2002
spiked
Signet House
49-51
Farringdon Road
London, EC1M 3JP
Sandy
Starr is a contributor to The Internet: Brave New World?
(Hodder & Stoughton, 2002). Buy this book from Amazon (UK) or
Amazon (USA)
(1) See
the Ideas 21 and UK Patent Office websites
(2) See
the Miller Insurance Group website
(3) See
the Shook, Hardy and Bacon website
(4) See
the Commission on Intellectual Property Rights website
(5) Integrating
Intellectual Property Rights and Development Policy (.pdf 1.7 MB),
Commission on Intellectual Property Rights, September 2002, p6
(6) Meeting
Nelson's concerns about intellectual property (.pdf 74.4 KB), William
Kingston, 14 May 2001, p7
(7) See
the AllVoice Computing plc website
(8) Enforcing
Small Firms' Patent Rights (.pdf 308 KB), William Kingston, 2000,
p11
(9) Integrating
Intellectual Property Rights and Development Policy (.pdf 1.7 MB),
Commission on Intellectual Property Rights, September 2002, p124
(10)
See the Reuzip website
(11)
Integrating Intellectual Property Rights and Development Policy (.pdf
1.7 MB), Commission on Intellectual Property Rights, September 2002,
p21
(12)
Integrating Intellectual Property Rights and Development Policy (.pdf
1.7 MB), Commission on Intellectual Property Rights, September 2002,
p112