Integrating
Intellectual Property Rights
and Development Policy
Report of the
Commission on Intellectual Property Rights
London
September 2002
Published by
Commission on Intellectual Property Rights
c/o DFID
1 Palace Street
London SW1E 5HE
Tel: 020 7023 0000
Fax: 020 7023 0016 (for the attention of Charles Clift)
Email: ipr@dfid.gov.uk
Website: http://www.iprcommission.org
September 2002
The full text of the report and the executive summary can be downloaded from the CIPR website: http://www.iprcommission.org
For a hard copy of the report or further information please contact the Commission Secretariat at the above address.
© Commission on Intellectual Property Rights 2002
Designed and Printed by
Dsprint/redesign
7 Jute Lane
Brimsdown
Enfield EN3 7JL
George E. Osborne Professor of Law, Stanford University, California, USA
Barrister specialising in Intellectual
Property Law, London, UK
Director, Masters Programme on Science and Technology Policy and Management, University of Buenos Aires, Argentina
Director General, Indian Council of Scientific and Industrial Research and Secretary to the Department of Scientific and Industrial Research, Delhi, India
Senior Director of Science Policy and Scientific Affairs (Europe) at Pfizer Inc., Sandwich, UK
Director of Nuffield Council on Bioethics, London, UK
Charles Clift – Head
Phil Thorpe – Policy Analyst
Tom Pengelly – Policy Analyst
Rob Fitter – Research Officer
Brian Penny – Office Manager
Carol Oliver – Personal Assistant
PREFACE
Clare Short, the Secretary of State for International Development, established the Commission on Intellectual Property Rights in May 2001. We are made up of members from a diversity of countries, backgrounds and perspectives. We have each brought very different viewpoints to the table. We incorporate voices from both developed and developing countries: from science, law, ethics and economics and from industry, government and academia.
I believe that it is a considerable achievement that there is so much that we have been able to agree on about our approach and our basic message. As our title implies, we consider that development objectives need to be integrated into the making of policy on intellectual property rights, both nationally and internationally, and our report sets out ways in which this could be put into practice.
Although appointed by the British Government, we have been given absolute freedom to set our own agenda, devise our own programme of work, and come to our own conclusions and recommendations. We have been given the opportunity and financial support to improve our understanding of the issues through commissioning studies, organising workshops and conferences, and visiting officials and affected groups throughout the world. We have been supported by a wonderfully capable Secretariat supplied by the DFID and the UK Patent Office, and we want to thank them especially.
We first met on 8-9 May 2001, and have held seven meetings since. All or some of us have visited Brazil, China, India, Kenya, and South Africa, and we have consulted with public sector officials, the private sector and NGOs in London, Brussels, Geneva, and Washington. We visited the Pfizer research facility in Sandwich. A list of the main institutions we have consulted appears at the end of the report. We have commissioned seventeen working papers and held eight workshops in London on various aspects of intellectual property. And we held a large conference in London on 21-22 February 2002 to ensure that we could hear questions and concerns from many perspectives. We regard these sessions as important parts of our work in their own right. They brought together a range of individuals with a view to facilitating dialogue and exploring the scope for moving some of the issues forward.
On behalf of all of us I want to thank all those people from all over the world, far too numerous to mention, who provided input to our discussions and who prepared working papers.
Our tasks were to consider:
· how national IPR regimes could best be designed to benefit developing countries within the context of international agreements, including TRIPS;
· how the international framework of rules and agreements might be improved and developed – for instance in the area of traditional knowledge – and the relationship between IPR rules and regimes covering access to genetic resources;
· the broader policy framework needed to complement intellectual property regimes including for instance controlling anti-competitive practices through competition policy and law.
We decided early on not just to attempt to suggest compromises among different
interest groups, but to be as evidence-based as possible. This has been challenging, for there is
often limited or inconclusive evidence, but our Secretariat, extensive
consultations, and the papers we commissioned, helped us in identifying the available
evidence, which we then carefully evaluated.
We also recognised early on the importance of distinguishing nations
(middle or low income) which have substantial scientific and technological
capability from those which do not. We attempted to learn about the real
impacts of intellectual property, both positive and negative, in each of these
groups of nations. We chose to
concentrate on the concerns of the poorest, both in low and middle income
nations.
We all concur in this report. Our aim
is practical and balanced solutions. In
some cases we have adopted suggestions made by others but the responsibility
for the conclusions is ours alone. We
hope that we have fulfilled our task and that the report will be a valuable
resource to all those engaged in the debate on how intellectual property rights
might better serve to promote development and reduce poverty.
Finally I want to thank Clare Short, and the UK Department for International Development, for their foresight in creating the Commission on Intellectual Property Rights. I have been honoured to chair it. It has been an extraordinary experience for me, and for all of us on the Commission. We received a challenging remit. We greatly enjoyed our task and the opportunity to learn from one another and, in particular, from the many who have contributed to our work.
Chairman
FOREWORD
There are few concerned with IP who will find
that this report makes entirely comfortable reading. No
greater compliment can be paid to Professor Barton and his team of
Commissioners. Nor can there be any
greater indication of the foresight and courage of Clare Short, the UK
Secretary of State for International Development, in creating the Commission
and setting its terms of reference in the first place.
Perhaps there is something about the era we
live in that has encouraged blind adherence to dogma. This has affected many walks of life. It certainly has affected
the whole area of intellectual property rights. On the one side, the developed world side, there exists a
powerful lobby of those who believe that all IPRs are good for business,
benefit the public at large and act as catalysts for technical progress. They
believe and argue that, if IPRs are good, more IPRs must be better. On the other side, the developing world
side, there exists a vociferous lobby of those who believe that IPRs are likely
to cripple the development of local industry and technology, will harm the
local population and benefit none but the developed world. They believe and argue that, if IPRs are
bad, the fewer the better. The process
of implementing TRIPS has not resulted in a shrinking of the gap that divides
these two sides, rather it has helped to reinforce the views already held. Those in favour of more IPRs and the
creation of a “level playing field” hail TRIPS as a useful tool with which to
achieve their objectives. On the other
hand those who believe that IPRs are bad for developing countries believe that
the economic playing field was uneven before TRIPS and that its introduction
has reinforced the inequality. So
firmly and sincerely held are these views that at times it has appeared that
neither side has been prepared to listen to the other. Persuasion is out, compulsion is in.
Whether IPRs are a good or bad thing, the
developed world has come to an accommodation with them over a long period. Even if their disadvantages sometimes
outweigh their advantages, by and large the developed world has the national
economic strength and established legal mechanisms to overcome the problems so
caused. Insofar as their benefits outweigh their disadvantages, the developed
world has the wealth and infrastructure to take advantage of the opportunities
provided. It is likely that neither of
these holds true for developing and least developed countries.
It is against that background that the
Secretary of State decided to set up the Commission and ask it to consider,
amongst other things, how national IPR rights could best be designed to benefit
developing countries. Inherent in that
remit was the acknowledgement that IPRs could be a tool which could help or
hinder more fragile economies. The
Commissioners themselves represent as impressive a cross-section of relevant
expertise as one could wish. They have
consulted widely. This report is the result.
It is most impressive.
Although the terms of reference have
required the Commission to pay particular regard to the interests of developing
countries, it has done this without ignoring the interests and arguments of
those from the other side. As it
states, higher IP standards should not be pressed on developing countries
without a serious and objective assessment of their development impact. The Commission has gone a long way to
providing such an assessment. This has produced a report which contains
sensible proposals designed to meet most of the reasonable requirements of both
sides.
However, the production of a series of
workable proposals is not enough by itself. What is needed is an acceptance and
will to implement them. Once again, in
this respect the Commission is playing a major role. This is not the report of a pressure group. The Commission was
set up to offer as impartial advice as possible. Its provenance and makeup should encourage all those to whom it
is directed to take its recommendations seriously.
For too long IPRs have been
regarded as food for the rich countries and poison for poor countries. I hope that this report demonstrates that
it is not as simple as that. Poor countries may find them useful provided
they are accommodated to suit local palates. The Commission suggests that the appropriate
diet for each developing country needs to be decided on the basis of what is
best for its development, and that the international community and governments
in all countries should take decisions with that in mind. I very much hope this report will stimulate
them to do so.
UK
High Court Patents Judge
OVERVIEW
1
INTRODUCTION 1
BACKGROUND 2
OUR TASK 6
Chapter
1: INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY AND DEVELOPMENT 13
INTRODUCTION 13
THE
RATIONALE FOR IP PROTECTION 15
Introduction
Patents
Copyright
HISTORY 20
THE
EVIDENCE ABOUT IP 23
The
Context
Redistributive Impact
Growth
and Innovation
Trade
and Investment
TECHNOLOGY
TRANSFER 28
Chapter
2: HEALTH 34
INTRODUCTION 34
The
Issue
Background
RESEARCH
AND DEVELOPMENT 37
Research
Incentives
ACCESS
TO MEDICINES FOR POOR PEOPLE 40
Prevalence
of Patenting
Patents
and Prices
Other
Factors Affecting Access
POLICY
IMPLICATIONS 46
National
Policy Options
Compulsory
Licensing for Countries with Insufficient Manufacturing Capacity
Developing
Country Legislation
Doha
Extension for Least Developed Countries
Chapter
3: AGRICULTURE AND GENETIC RESOURCES 65
INTRODUCTION 65
Background
Intellectual
Property Rights in Agriculture
PLANTS
AND INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY PROTECTION 67
Introduction
Research
and Development
The
Impact of Plant Variety Protection
The
Impact of Patents
Conclusion
ACCESS
TO PLANT GENETIC RESOURCES AND FARMERS’ RIGHTS 76
Introduction
Farmers’
Rights
The
Multilateral System
Chapter 4: TRADITIONAL KNOWLEDGE, ACCESS AND BENEFIT SHARING
AND GEOGRAPHICAL
INDICATIONS 82
INTRODUCTION 82
TRADITIONAL
KNOWLEDGE 83
Background
The
Nature of Traditional Knowledge and the Purpose of Protection
Managing
the Debate on Traditional Knowledge
Making
Use of the Existing IP System to Protect and Promote Traditional Knowledge
Sui Generis Protection of Traditional Knowledge
Misappropriation
of Traditional Knowledge
ACCESS
AND BENEFIT SHARING 93
Background
Convention
on Biological Diversity (CBD)
Disclosing
the Geographical Origin of Genetic Resources in Patent Applications
GEOGRAPHICAL INDICATIONS 98
Background
Geographical
Indications and TRIPS
Multilateral
Register of Geographical Indications
The Economic Impact of Geographical Indications
Chapter
5: COPYRIGHT, SOFTWARE AND THE INTERNET 105
INTRODUCTION 105
COPYRIGHT
AS A STIMULUS TO CREATION 106
Collecting
Societies
WILL
COPYRIGHT RULES ALLOW DEVELOPING COUNTRIES TO CLOSE
THE KNOWLEDGE GAP? 109
COPYRIGHT-BASED
INDUSTRIES AND COPYING OF PROTECTED WORKS 111
COPYRIGHT
AND ACCESS 113
Educational
Materials
Libraries
COPYRIGHT
AND COMPUTER SOFTWARE 116
DELIVERING
THE POTENTIAL OF THE INTERNET FOR DEVELOPMENT 117
Technological
restrictions
Chapter
6: PATENT REFORM 123
INTRODUCTION 123
THE DESIGN OF PATENT SYSTEMS IN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES 126
Introduction
Scope of
Patentability
Patentability
Standards
Exceptions
to Patent Rights
Providing
Safeguards in a Patent Policy
Encouraging
Domestic Innovation
Conclusions
THE USE
OF THE PATENT SYSTEM IN PUBLIC SECTOR RESEARCH 137
Introduction
Evidence
from the United States
Evidence
from Developing Countries
HOW THE
PATENT SYSTEM MIGHT INHIBIT RESEARCH AND INNOVATION 140
The
Issues in Developed Countries
The
Relevance to Developing Countries
INTERNATIONAL
PATENT HARMONISATION 146
Background
WIPO
Substantive Patent Law Treaty
Chapter
7: INSTITUTIONAL CAPACITY 153
INTRODUCTION 153
IP
POLICY MAKING AND LEGISLATION 153
Integrated
Policy Making
IPR
ADMINISTRATION AND INSTITUTIONS 156
Introduction
Human
Resources
Information
Technologies
EXAMINATION
VERSUS REGISTRATION SYSTEMS 159
Regional
or International Co-operation
COSTS
AND REVENUES 161
The cost
of an IP system
Meeting
the costs
ENFORCEMENT 163
Enforcement
in developing countries
Enforcement
in developed countries
REGULATIING
INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS 165
TECHNICAL
ASSISTANCE AND CAPACITY BUILDING 167
Current
programs
Assessing
the impact of technical assistance
Financing
further technical assistance
Ensuring
effective delivery of technical assistance
Chapter 8: THE INTERNATIONAL
ARCHITECTURE 172
INTRODUCTION 172
INTERNATIONAL
STANDARD SETTING: WIPO AND WTO 173
THE
TRIPS AGREEMENT 177
Assisting
developing countries to implement TRIPS
Timetable
for implementing TRIPS
IP IN
BILATERAL AND REGIONAL AGREEMENTS 180
DEVELOPING
COUNTRY PARTICIPATION 182
Permanent
representation in Geneva
Expert
Delegations
THE ROLE
OF CIVIL SOCIETY 184
DEEPENING UNDERSTANDING ABOUT IP AND DEVELOPMENT 185
ACRONYMS 189
OVERVIEW
The Millennium Development Goals recognise the crucial importance of reducing poverty and hunger, improving health and education, and ensuring environmental sustainability. The international community has set itself the target of reducing the proportion of people in poverty by half by 2015, along with associated specific targets for improving health and education and environmental sustainability.
It is estimated that in 1999 nearly 1.2 billion people lived on less than $1 a day, and nearly 2.8 billion people on less than $2 per day.[1] About 65% of these are in South and East Asia, and a further 25% in sub-Saharan Africa. There were an estimated 3 million deaths from HIV/AIDS in 2001, 2.3 million of them in sub-Saharan Africa.[2] Tuberculosis (TB) accounts for nearly 1.7 million deaths worldwide.[3] On present trends, there will be 10.2 million new cases in 2005.[4] There are also over 1 million deaths annually from malaria.[5] In 1999 there were still 120 million children not in primary school. Sub-Saharan Africa has the lowest current enrolment rate at 60%.[6]
It is our task to consider whether and how intellectual property rights (IPRs) could play a role in helping the world meet these targets – in particular by reducing poverty, helping to combat disease, improving the health of mothers and children, enhancing access to education and contributing to sustainable development. It is also our task to consider whether and how they present obstacles to meeting those targets and, if so, how those obstacles can be removed.
Some argue strongly that IPRs are necessary to stimulate economic growth which, in turn, contributes to poverty reduction. By stimulating invention and new technologies, they will increase agricultural or industrial production, promote domestic and foreign investment, facilitate technology transfer and improve the availability of medicines necessary to combat disease. They take the view that there is no reason why a system that works for developed countries could not do the same in developing countries.
Others argue equally vehemently the opposite. IP rights do little to stimulate invention in developing countries, because the necessary human and technical capacity may be absent. They are ineffective at stimulating research to benefit poor people because they will not be able to afford the products, even if developed. They limit the option of technological learning through imitation. They allow foreign firms to drive out domestic competition by obtaining patent protection and to service the market through imports, rather than domestic manufacture. Moreover, they increase the costs of essential medicines and agricultural inputs, affecting poor people and farmers particularly badly.
In assessing these opposing arguments, it is important to remember the technological disparity between developed and developing countries as a group. Low and middle income developing countries account for about 21% of world GDP,[7] but for less than 10% of worldwide research and development (R&D) expenditure.[8] The OECD countries spend far more on R&D than India’s total national income.[9] Almost without exception, developing countries are net importers of technology.
It is essential to consider the diversity of developing countries in respect of their social and economic circumstances and technological capabilities. Altogether more than 60% of the world’s poor live in countries that have significant scientific and technological capabilities, and the great majority of them live in China and India. China and India, along with several other smaller developing countries, have world class capacity in a number of scientific and technological areas including, for instance, space, nuclear energy, computing, biotechnology, pharmaceuticals, software development and aviation.[10] By contrast, 25% of poor people live in Sub-Saharan Africa (excluding South Africa), mainly in countries with relatively weak technical capacity.[11] It is estimated that in 1994 China, India and Latin America together accounted for nearly 9% of worldwide research expenditure, but sub-Saharan Africa accounted for only 0.5% and developing countries other than India and China only about 4%.[12]
Thus developing countries are far from homogeneous, a fact which is self-evident but often forgotten. Not only do their scientific and technical capacities vary, but also their social and economic structures, and their inequalities of income and wealth. The determinants of poverty, and therefore the appropriate policies to address it, will vary accordingly between countries. The same applies to policies on IPRs. Policies required in countries with a relatively advanced technological capability where most poor people happen to live, for instance India or China, may well differ from those in other countries with a weak capability, such as many countries in sub-Saharan Africa. The impact of IP policies on poor people will also vary according to socio-economic circumstances. What works in India, will not necessarily work in Brazil or Botswana.
BACKGROUND
Over the last twenty years or so there has been an unprecedented increase in the level, scope, territorial extent and role of IP right protection.[13] Manifestations of this include:
· The patenting of living things and materials found in nature, as opposed to man-made products and processes more readily recognisable to the layman as inventions
· The modification of protection regimes to accommodate new technologies (particularly biotechnology and information technology), such as the EU Biotechnology Directive[14] or the Digital Millennium Copyright Act (DMCA) in the United States (US)
· The extension of protection into new areas such as software and business methods, and the adoption in some countries of new sui generis regimes for semiconductors and databases
· A new emphasis on the protection of new knowledge and technologies produced in the public sector
· The focus on the relationship between IP protection and traditional knowledge,[15] folklore and genetic resources
· The geographical extension of minimum standards for IP protection through the TRIPS agreement (see Box O.1), and of higher standards through bilateral and regional trade and investment agreements
· The widening of exclusive rights, extension of the duration of protection, and strengthening of enforcement mechanisms.
Box O.1 The World Trade Organisation and the TRIPS Agreement
The Agreement on
Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS)[16]
emerged from the Uruguay Round of trade negotiations completed in 1994. The
Final Act of these negotiations created the World Trade Organisation (WTO) and
set out rules – the WTO Agreements including TRIPS – with which members of the
WTO have to comply. A dispute
settlement system was also streamlined to resolve trade disputes between WTO
Members. The WTO, as of January this year, has 144 Members, accounting for over
90% of world trade. Over 30 further
countries are negotiating membership.
TRIPS requires all WTO Members to provide minimum
standards of protection for a wide range of IPRs including copyright, patents,
trademarks, industrial designs, geographical indications, semiconductor
topographies and undisclosed information.
In doing so, TRIPS incorporates provisions from many existing IP
international agreements such as the Paris and Berne Conventions administered
by the World Intellectual Property Organisation (WIPO). TRIPS however also introduces a number of
new obligations, particularly in relation to geographical indications, patents,
trade secrets, and measures governing how IP rights should be enforced.
A special body, the Council for TRIPS (commonly known
as the TRIPS Council), on which each WTO Member is represented, was established
to administer the operation of the TRIPS.
The TRIPS Council is responsible for reviewing various aspects of TRIPS
as mandated in the agreement itself and also as requested by the biennial WTO
Ministerial Conference.
Among the issues raised by TRIPS that have provoked
the most discussion are:
·
whether the
objective set out in Article 7 that IPRs should contribute to the transfer of
technology is achievable, particularly in respect of developing country members
of the WTO.
·
the perceived
tensions between Article 8 which allows countries to adopt measures necessary
to protect public health, and to prevent abuses of IP rights, provided they are
TRIPS consistent, and other requirements in the agreement. These include the requirements to provide
patent protection for pharmaceutical products, limitations on the conditions
for issuing of compulsory licences (Article 31) and on the scope of provisions providing
exceptions to patent rights (Article 30).
·
the
requirement to protect test data against “unfair commercial use” in Article
39.
·
the
justification for providing additional protection for geographical indications
for wines and spirits, (Article 23) and whether this additional protection
should also be extended to cover other or all geographical indications.
·
the extent to
which patents should be allowed on inventions relating to living forms, for
example microorganisms (Article 27.3(b)), and the requirement to provide IP
protection for plants. In that context,
the compatibility of TRIPS with agreements such as the Convention on Biological
Diversity (CBD) has been raised.
·
the cost of
meeting the requirements of TRIPS for many developing and least developed WTO
Members in relation to the administration of IP rights and their effective
enforcement.
TRIPS took effect on 1 January 1995. WTO Members
considered as developed countries were given one year to comply whilst
developing countries and transition economies were given until 1 January 2000
although for developing countries required to extend product patent protection
to new areas such as pharmaceuticals, a further five years was provided before
such protection had to be introduced. Least Developed Countries (LDCs)[17]
are expected to enact TRIPS by 2006 although the Doha Ministerial Declaration
on the TRIPS Agreement and Public Health allowed them a further 10 years in
respect of pharmaceutical products.
Where there are disputes over the interpretation of TRIPS and its implementation by national laws, members may bring cases to the WTO’s Disputes Settlement Body (DSB) to resolve. To date there have been 24 cases involving TRIPS, where the disputes procedures have been invoked. Of these 23 were brought by developed country members, and one by Brazil. Sixteen were disputes between developed countries, seven were cases brought by developed against developing countries, and one by Brazil against the US. Of the 24, ten have been settled by mutual agreement, seven were decided by panels set up under the procedure, and seven are still pending.
The concerns about the operation of the intellectual property system and the extension of IPRs are not confined to their application to developing countries. There are currently two prominent enquiries in the US, one by the National Academies of Science and one by the Department of Justice and the Federal Trade Commission, looking at this important question.[18] These concerns centre on the rapid increase in patent applications in the US in recent years (a more than 50% increase in the last five years), and the perception that many more patents of “low quality” and broad scope are being issued. A fear is commonly expressed that too many patents have been and may be granted in respect of developments of minor importance. For instance, in the pharmaceutical industry, this can have the effect of prolonging monopolies on valuable therapies. Patents may also be granted in some jurisdictions over biological materials on the grounds that they have been isolated from nature, if a possible function or utility is identified. The extent to which such practices affect competition by making it more difficult for rival inventors to sell competing products or more expensive for consumers to buy them is a matter of concern and growing debate. Considerable debate also exists about their effect on research, particularly in software and biotechnology, where patents taken at an early stage in the research process may be an obstacle to downstream research and commercialisation.
In a seminal article, the biologist Garrett Hardin[19] coined the phrase “tragedy of the commons” to explain how common resources tended to be overutilised in the absence of rules for their use. The proliferation of IPRs, particularly in areas such as biomedical research, has suggested the possibility of “a different tragedy, an “anticommons” in which people underuse scarce resources because too many owners can block each other…more intellectual property rights may lead paradoxically to fewer useful products for improving human health”.[20] Companies may now incur considerable costs, in time and money, determining how to do research without infringing other companies’ patent rights, or defending their own patent rights against other companies. This gives rise to a question as to whether the substantial costs involved in patent searching, analysis and litigation are a necessary price to pay for the incentives offered by the patent system, or whether ways can be found to reduce them.
The issues are not confined to patents. In the US, the term of copyright has extended in the last century from 28 years (renewable for a further 28 years) under the 1909 Copyright Act to 70 years after the death of the author, or 95 years from publication (in line with European practice). The question is whether this extension of protection can credibly be regarded as enhancing the incentives for future creation, or whether it is more about enhancing the value of existing creations. In 1998, Congress passed the Digital Millennium Copyright Act (DMCA) which, inter alia, forbids the circumvention of technological protection (i.e. encryption). In Europe, the Database Directive requires all Member States to provide sui generis protection for any collection of data arranged in a systematic way, whether the data itself is original or not. So far the US has not followed this approach. Increasingly there is concern that protection, under the influence of commercial pressures insufficiently circumscribed by considerations of public interest, is being extended more for the purpose of protecting the value of investments than to stimulate invention or creation.
We think that the concerns about the impact of IP in the US and other developed countries are important for developing countries as well. But we consider that, if anything, the costs of getting the IP system “wrong” in a developing country are likely to be far higher than in developed countries. Most developed countries have sophisticated systems of competition regulation to ensure that abuses of any monopoly rights cannot unduly affect the public interest. In the US and the EU, for example, these regimes are particularly strong and well-established. In most developing countries this is far from being case. This makes such countries particularly vulnerable to inappropriate intellectual property systems. We consider that developing countries can seek to learn from the experience of developed countries in devising their own intellectual property systems suitable to their particular legal system and economic situation.
Apart from the impact of local intellectual property rules internally in a developing country, there are also indirect impacts of the developed country intellectual property system on developing countries. In the digital age, restrictions on access to materials and data on the Internet affect everyone. Scientists in developing countries, for instance, may be prevented from gaining access to protected data, or have insufficient resources to do so. Research on important diseases or new crops affecting developing countries, but carried out in developed countries, may be hampered or promoted by the IP system. The IP regime in developed countries may provide powerful incentives to do research of particular kinds which mainly benefit people in developed countries, diverting intellectual resources from work on problems of global significance. Practice in developed countries may allow knowledge or genetic resources originating in developing countries to be patented without prior arrangements for sharing any benefits from commercialisation. In some cases developing country exports to developed countries may be restricted as a result of such protection.
Equally important for developing countries is the continuing trend towards the global harmonisation of IP protection. The movement towards harmonisation is not new – it has been going on for over 100 years. However the TRIPS agreement, that entered into force, subject to specified transitional periods, in 1995 (see Box O.1) has made minimum standards of IP protection mandatory for WTO members. But TRIPS is only one element of international harmonisation. There are continuing discussions in WIPO aimed at further harmonisation of the patent system, which may supersede TRIPS. Moreover, bilateral or regional trade and investment agreements between developed and developing countries often include mutual commitments to implement IP regimes that go beyond TRIPS minimum standards. Thus there is sustained pressure on developing countries to increase the levels of IP protection in their own regimes, based on standards in developed countries.
We have also been struck by the inconclusive and contested nature of much of the economic research devoted to elucidating the impact of IPRs, even in relation to the developed world. There is much that is uncertain, and given the nature of the subject, may remain so. The impact of IPRs is very often contingent on particular circumstances and context. Many academic observers, for this reason, remain determinedly ambivalent as to whether the social benefits of IPRs exceed their costs. Typical of these is the following example:
“It is almost impossible to conceive of any
existing social institution {the patent system} so faulty in so many ways. It survives only because there seems nothing
better to do.”[21]
In the case of developing countries, several recent reports by international agencies have commented on the likely impact of the globalisation of IP protection on developing countries.[22] All of these reports reflect to varying extents a concern that heavy costs may be incurred, but that the benefits for many countries are less easy to identify.
We take the setting up of our Commission to be evidence that the British government is sensitive to these concerns. In that light our fundamental task is to consider whether the rules and institutions of IP protection as they have evolved to date can contribute to development and the reduction of poverty in developing countries.
Our starting point is that some IP protection is likely to be appropriate at some stage for developing countries, as it has been historically for developed countries. There is no doubt that it can make an important contribution to research and innovation in developed countries, particularly in industries such as pharmaceuticals and chemicals. The system provides the incentive for individuals and companies to invent and develop new technologies that may benefit society. But incentives work differently according to whether there is a capacity to respond to them. And, by conferring exclusive rights, costs are imposed on consumers and other users of protected technologies. In some cases, protection means that potential consumers or users, who are unable to pay the prices charged by IP owners, are deprived of access to the innovations the IP system is intended to make available. The balance of costs and benefits will vary according to how rights are applied and economic and social circumstances. Standards of IP protection that may be suitable for developed countries may cause greater costs than benefits when applied in developing countries which must rely in large part on knowledge or products embodying knowledge generated elsewhere to satisfy basic needs and foster their development.
The Nature of Intellectual Property Rights
Some see IP rights principally as economic or commercial rights, and others as akin to political or human rights. The TRIPS agreement treats them in the former sense, while recognising the need to strike a balance between the rights of inventors and creators to protection, and the rights of users of technology (Article 7 of TRIPS). The Universal Declaration of Human Rights has a broader definition recognising “the right to the protection of the moral and material interests resulting from any scientific, literary or artistic production of which he is the author”, balanced by “the right…to share in scientific advancement and its benefits”.[23] The crucial issue is to reconcile the public interest in accessing new knowledge and the products of new knowledge, with the public interest in stimulating invention and creation which produces the new knowledge and products on which material and cultural progress may depend.
The difficulty is that the IP system seeks to achieve this reconciliation by conferring a private right, and private material benefits. Thus the (human) right to the protection of “moral and material interests” of “authors” is inextricably bound up with the right to the private material benefits which result from such protection. And the private benefit to the creator or inventor is derived at the expense of the consumer. Particularly where the consumer is poor, this may conflict with basic human rights, for example, the right to life. And the IP system, as manifested in TRIPS, does not allow – except in rather narrow ways - discrimination between goods essential to life or education, and other goods such as films or fast food.
We therefore consider that an IP right is best viewed as one of the means by which nations and societies can help to promote the fulfilment of human economic and social rights. In particular, there are no circumstances in which the most fundamental human rights should be subordinated to the requirements of IP protection. IP rights are granted by states for limited times (at least in the case of patents and copyrights) whereas human rights are inalienable and universal.[24]
For the most part IP rights are nowadays generally treated as economic and commercial rights, as is the case in TRIPS, and are more often held by companies rather than individual inventors. But describing them as “rights” should not be allowed to conceal the very real dilemmas raised by their application in developing countries, where the extra costs they impose may be at the expense of the essential prerequisites of life for poor people.
Regardless of the term used for them, we prefer to regard IPRs as instruments of public policy which confer economic privileges on individuals or institutions solely for the purposes of contributing to the greater public good. The privilege is therefore a means to an end, not an end in itself.
Thus in terms of assessing the value of IP protection, it may be compared to taxation. Hardly anybody claims that the more taxation there is, the better. However, there is a tendency among some to treat more IP protection as self-evidently a good thing. More taxation might be desirable if it delivers public services that society values more than the direct and indirect cost of taxation. But less can also be beneficial, for instance if excessive taxation is harming economic growth. Moreover, economists and politicians spend much time considering whether the structure of the tax system is optimal. Are heavy social security taxes harming employment? Are particular tax breaks serving their intended purpose, or merely subsidising their recipients to do what they are already doing? Is the effect of the tax system on the distribution of income desirable from a social point of view?
We think there are very analogous questions for intellectual property. How much of it is a good thing? How should it be structured? How does the optimal structure vary with sectors and levels of development? Moreover, even if we get the level and structure of protection right, to balance the incentive to invention and creation against the costs to society, we also have to worry about the distribution of gains.
Equitable Sharing of Benefits and Costs
The immediate impact of intellectual property protection is to benefit financially those who have knowledge and inventive power, and to increase the costs of access to those without. This is obviously relevant to the distribution of gains between developed and developing societies. Even if there were economic gains to the world as a whole from extending protection, on which there is some debate, the distributional consequences for income may not accord with our sense of equity. In the majority of developing countries, with weak scientific and technical infrastructures, the benefits in the form of the stimulus to domestic innovation will be muted, but they will still face the costs arising from the protection of (mainly foreign) technologies. Thus the costs and the benefits of the system as a whole may not be fairly distributed.
If most developing countries do not have a strong technological base which could benefit from IP protection, they do have genetic resources and traditional knowledge, which have value both to them and to the world at large. These are not necessarily IP resources in the sense that they are understood in developed countries, but they are certainly resources on the basis of which protected intellectual property can be, and has been, created. This raises a number of difficult issues as to whether and how these resources should interact with, and be valued by, the “modern” IP system, the extent to which these resources and knowledge require their own protection (not just in the IP sense), and how commercial benefits derived from these resources should be equitably shared.
The Internet also offers enormous opportunities for access to information required by developing countries, in particular scientists and researchers, whose access to printed media may be limited by lack of resources. But there is a concern that forms of encryption (or “digital rights management”), designed to counter widespread copying, will make material less accessible than is now the case with printed media. Such trends endanger the concept of “fair use”[25] (and similar doctrines) as it applies now to printed works, and at the extreme may provide the equivalent of perpetual copyright protection, by technological rather than legal means.
How
Should Intellectual Property Policy be Made?
When there is so much uncertainty and controversy about the global impact of IPRs, we believe it is incumbent on policy makers to consider the available evidence, imperfect as it may be, before further extending property rights in scope or territorial extent.
Too often the interests of the “producer” dominate in the evolution of IP policy, and that of the ultimate consumer is neither heard nor heeded. So policy tends to be determined more by the interests of the commercial users of the system, than by an impartial conception of the greater public good. In IPR discussions between developed and developed countries, a similar imbalance exists. The trade ministries of developed nations are mainly influenced by producer interests who see the benefit to them of stronger IP protection in their export markets, while the consumer nations, mainly the developing countries, are less able to identify and represent their own interests against those of the developed nations.
Thus we recognise that the rules and practices of intellectual property, and how they evolve, are the product of political economy. Developing countries - and in particular poor consumers of products which may be protected by IP rights - negotiate from a position of relative weakness. There is a fundamental asymmetry in relationships between developed and developing countries, based ultimately on their relative economic strength.
The negotiations on TRIPS in the Uruguay Round are but one example. Developing countries accepted TRIPS not because at the time the adoption of intellectual property protection was high on their list of priorities, but partly because they thought the overall package offered, including the reduction of trade protectionism in developed countries, would be beneficial. Now many of them feel that the commitments made by developed countries to liberalise agriculture and textiles and reduce tariffs, have not been honoured, while they have to live with the burdens of the TRIPS agreement. The agreement on a new “development” WTO Round at Doha last year recognises that this bargain, between developed and developing countries, needs to be made explicit and meaningful.
The difficulty for developing countries in this context is that they are “second comers” in a world that has been shaped by the “first comers”. And because of that, it is a very different world from that in which the “first comers” developed. It is a cliché to say that we live in an age of globalisation, when the world economy is becoming more integrated. It is an article of faith in the international community that integration on appropriate terms into the world economy is a necessary condition for development. The question from our point of view is what are the appropriate terms for that integration in the field of IPRs. Just as the now-developed countries moulded their IP regimes to suit their particular economic, social and technological circumstances, so developing countries should in principle now be able to do the same.
We therefore conclude that far more attention needs to be accorded to the needs of the developing countries in the making of international IP policy. Consistent with recent decisions of the international community at Doha and Monterrey, the development objectives need to be integrated into the making of IP rules and practice. At Monterrey in March 2002, governments welcomed “the decisions of the World Trade Organization to place the needs and interests of developing countries at the heart of its work programme”. They also acknowledged the concerns of developing countries, including:
“the lack of recognition of intellectual property rights for the
protection of traditional knowledge and folklore; the transfer of knowledge and
technology; the implementation and interpretation of the Agreement on
Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights in a manner supportive of
public health…”[26]
We believe this is a satisfactory but partial agenda. There is far more that needs to be thought about and done in considering the impact of the existing system upon developing countries. It is our contention that intellectual property systems may, if we are not careful, introduce distortions that are detrimental to the interests of developing countries. Very “high” standards of protection may be in the public interest in developed countries with highly sophisticated scientific and technological infrastructures (although we note, as above, that this is controversial in several respects), but this does not mean the same standards are appropriate in all developing countries. In fact we consider that developed countries should pay more attention to reconciling their own perceived commercial self-interest, with their own interest in the reduction of poverty in developing countries.
To achieve that end, so far as possible developing countries should not be deprived of the flexibility to design their IP systems that developed countries enjoyed in earlier stages of their own development, and higher IP standards should not be pressed on them without a serious and objective assessment of their development impact. We need to ensure that the global IP systems evolve so that they may contribute to the development of developing countries, by stimulating innovation and technology transfer relevant to them, while also making available the products of technology at the most competitive prices possible. We need to make sure that the IP system facilitates, rather than hinders, the application of the rapid advances in science and technology for the benefit of developing countries.
We hope our report will make a contribution by defining an agenda for making the global IPR system, and the institutions in that system, work better for poor people and developing countries.
We have identified a number of key issues for developing countries which we deal with in the following chapters:
· What can we learn from the economic and empirical evidence about the impact of IP in developing countries? Does the historical experience of developed countries hold any lessons for developing countries today? How can technology transfer to developing countries be facilitated? (Chapter 1)
· How does the IP system contribute to the development of medicines that are needed by poor people? How does it affect the access of poor people to medicines and their availability? What does this imply for IP rules and practices? (Chapter 2)
· Can IP protection on plants and genetic resources benefit developing countries and poor people? What sort of systems should developing countries consider for protecting plant varieties while safeguarding farmers’ rights? (Chapter 3)
· How could the IP system contribute to the principles of access and benefit sharing enshrined in the Convention on Biological Diversity (CBD)? Can it help to protect or promote traditional knowledge, biodiversity and cultural expressions? Can the extension of Geographical Indications[27] (GIs) benefit developing countries? (Chapter 4)
· How does copyright protection affect developing countries’ access to knowledge, technologies and information that they need? Will IP or technological protection affect access to the Internet? How can copyright be used to support creative industries in developing countries? (Chapter 5)
· How should developing countries frame their own legislation and practice on patents? Can developing countries frame their legislation in ways that might avoid some of the problems that have occurred in developed countries? What would be the best position for developing countries in relation to patent harmonisation? (Chapter 6)
· What sort of institutions do developing countries need to administer, enforce and regulate IP effectively and how can these be established? What complementary policies and institutions are necessary, in particular in relation to competition? (Chapter 7)
· Are the international and national institutions involved in IPRs as effective as they could be in serving the interests of developing countries? (Chapter 8)
Chapter 1
Intellectual property is a form of knowledge which societies have decided can be assigned specific property rights. They have some resemblance to ownership rights over physical property or land. But knowledge is much more than intellectual property. Knowledge is embodied in people, in institutions and in new technologies in ways that have long been seen as a major engine of economic growth.[28] Alfred Marshall, the “father” of modern economics, thought so in the 19th Century.[29] With recent scientific and technical advances, particularly in biotechnology and information and communications technologies (ICTs), knowledge has become to an even greater degree than before the principal source of competitive advantage for both companies and countries. Trade in high technology goods and services which are knowledge-intensive, and where IP protection is most common, tends to be among the fastest-growing in international trade.[30]
In developed countries, there is good evidence that intellectual property is, and has been, important for the promotion of invention in some industrial sectors, although the evidence as to exactly how important it is in different sectors is mixed. For example, evidence from the 1980s indicates that the pharmaceutical, chemical and petroleum industries were predominant in recognising that the patent system was essential to innovation.[31] Today, one would need to add biotechnology and some components of information technology. Copyright has also proven essential for the music, film and publishing industries.
For developing countries, like the developed countries before them, the development of indigenous technological capacity has proved to be a key determinant of economic growth and poverty reduction. This capacity determines the extent to which these countries can assimilate and apply foreign technology. Many studies have concluded the most distinctive single factor determining the success of technology transfer is the early emergence of an indigenous technological capacity.[32]
But developing countries vary widely in the quality and capacity of their scientific and technical infrastructures. A commonly used indicator of technological capability is the extent of patenting activity in the US and through international applications through the Patent Cooperation Treaty (PCT).[33] In 2001, less than 1% of US patents were granted to applicants from developing countries, nearly 60% of which were from seven of the more technologically advanced developing countries.[34] In the PCT, developing countries accounted for under 2% of applications in 1999-2001, with over 95% of these applications coming from just five countries: China, India, South Africa, Brazil and Mexico.[35] In these countries patent applications, although small, are growing faster than PCT applications generally. PCT applications grew by nearly 23% between 1999 and 2001, but the share of these countries in the total increased from 1% in 1999 to 2.6% in 2001. As we have seen R&D expenditure is heavily concentrated in developed countries, and in a few of the more technologically advanced developing countries. Few developing countries have been able to develop a strong indigenous technological capability. This means that it is difficult either for them to develop their own technology, or to assimilate technology from developed countries.
The crucial question is whether or not the extension of IP regimes assists developing countries in obtaining access to such technologies, and whether and how intellectual property right protection might help developing countries to achieve economic and social development and to reduce poverty. In this chapter we examine:
·
The rationale for IP protection
·
Its use historically in developed and
developing nations
·
The available evidence on the impact
of IP on developing countries
·
The role IP might have in facilitating
the transfer of technology to developing countries.
Box 1.1 What are Intellectual Property Rights?
Intellectual property (IP) rights are the rights awarded
by society to individuals or organisations principally over creative works:
inventions, literary and artistic works, and symbols, names, images, and
designs used in commerce. They give the creator the right to prevent others
from making unauthorised use of their property for a limited period. IP is
categorised as Industrial Property
(functional commercial innovations), and Artistic
and Literary Property (cultural creations). Current technological
developments are blurring, to some extent, this distinction, and some hybrid sui generis systems are emerging.
Patents: A patent is an exclusive right awarded to
an inventor to prevent others from making, selling, distributing, importing or
using their invention, without licence or authorisation, for a fixed period of
time (TRIPS stipulates 20 years minimum from filing date). In return, society
requires that the patent applicant disclose the invention in a manner that
enables others to put it into practice. This increases the body of knowledge
available for further research. As well
as sufficient disclosure of the invention, there are three requirements
(although details differ from country to country) that determine the
patentability of an invention: novelty (new characteristics which are not
"prior art")[36],
non-obviousness (an inventive step not obvious to one skilled in the field),
and utility (as used in the US) or industrial applicability (as used in the
UK). Utility models are similar to patents, but in some countries confer rights
of shorter duration to certain kinds of small or incremental innovations.
Industrial Designs:
Industrial designs protect the aesthetic aspects (shape, texture,
pattern, colour) of an object, rather than the technical features. TRIPS
requires that an original design be eligible for protection from unauthorised
use by others for a minimum of 10 years.
Trademarks:
Trademarks provide exclusive rights to use distinctive signs, such as
symbols, colours, letters, shapes or names to identify the producer of a product,
and protect its associated reputation.
In order to be eligible for protection a mark
must be distinctive of the proprietor so as to identify the proprietor’s goods
or services. The main purpose of a
trademark is to prevent customers from being misled or deceived. The period of protection varies, but
a trademark can be renewed indefinitely.
In addition many countries provide protection against unfair
competition, sometimes by way of preventing misrepresentations as to trade origin
regardless of registration of the trademark.
Geographical Indications:
Geographical Indications (GIs) identify the specific geographical origin
of a product, and the associated qualities, reputation or other
characteristics. They usually consist of the name of the place of origin. For
example, food products sometimes have qualities that derive from their place of
production and local environmental factors. The geographical indication
prevents unauthorized parties from using a protected GI for products not from
that region or from misleading the public as to the true origin of the
product.
Trade Secrets: Trade secrets consist of commercially
valuable information about production methods, business plans, clientele,
etc. They are protected as long as they
remain secret by laws which prevent acquisition by commercially unfair means
and unauthorised disclosure.
Copyright:
Copyright grants exclusive rights to the creators of original literary,
scientific and artistic works. Copyright only prevents copying, not
independent derivation. Copyright
protection begins, without formalities, with the creation of the work, and
lasts (as a general rule) for the life of the creator plus 50 years (70 years
in the US and EU). It prevents unauthorised reproduction,
public performance, recording, broadcasting, translation, or adaptation, and
allows the collection of royalties for authorised use. Computer programs are protected by
copyrights, as software source and code have been defined as a literary expression.
Integrated Computer Circuits: A specific sui generis form of protection for the design of integrated
computer circuits. As the inventive step is often minimal and originality is
the only requirement, the minimum period of protection under TRIPS is 10 years.
Plant Breeders’ Rights: Plant breeders’ rights (PBRs) are granted
to breeders of new, distinct, uniform and stable plant varieties. They normally offer protection for at least
fifteen years (counted from granting).
Most countries have exceptions for farmers to save and replant seeds,
and for the use of protected materials for further breeding.
Database Protection: The EU has adopted legislation to provide sui generis protection in respect of
databases, preventing unauthorised use of data compilations, even if
non-original. Exclusive rights to extract or utilize all or a substantial part
of the contents of the protected database are granted.
THE RATIONALE FOR IP PROTECTION
Introduction
Intellectual property creates a legal means to appropriate knowledge. A characteristic of knowledge is that one person’s use does not diminish another’s (for example, reading this report). Moreover the extra cost of extending use to another person is often very low or nil (for example, lending a book or copying an electronic file). From the point of view of society, the more people who use knowledge the better because each user gains something from it at low or no cost, and society is in some sense better off. Economists therefore say that knowledge has the character of a non-rival public good.[37]
The other aspect of knowledge, or products embodying knowledge, is the difficulty - often intrinsic - of preventing others from using or copying it. Many products, incorporating new knowledge, can be easily copied. Probably most products, with sufficient effort, can be copied at a fraction (albeit not necessarily small) of the cost it took to invent and market them. Economists refer to this latter characteristic as contributing to market failure. If a product takes considerable effort, ingenuity and research, but can be copied easily, there is unlikely to be a sufficient financial incentive from society’s point of view to devote resources to invention,
Patents are one way of addressing this market failure. By conferring temporary market exclusivities, patents allow producers to recoup the costs of investment in R&D and reap a profit, in return for making publicly available the knowledge on which the invention is based. However, someone else can only put that knowledge to potential commercial use with the authorisation of the patentee. The costs of investment in R&D and the return on that investment are met by charging the consumer a price based on the ability to exclude competition.
Protection is therefore a bargain struck by society on the premise that, in its absence, there would be insufficient invention and innovation. The assumption is that in the longer run, consumers will be better off, in spite of the higher costs conferred by monopoly pricing, because the short term losses to consumers are more than offset by the value to them of the new inventions created through additional R&D. Economists take the view that the patent system improves dynamic efficiency (by stimulating technical progress) at the cost of static efficiency (arising from the costs associated with monopoly).
This rationale for patent protection is relatively straightforward, but it is dependent on a number of simplifying assumptions that may not be borne out in practice. For instance, the optimal degree of patent protection cannot be accurately defined. If protection is too weak, then the development of technology may be inhibited through insufficient incentives for R&D. If too much protection is conferred, consumers may not benefit, even in the long run, and patentees may generate profits far in excess of the overall costs of R&D. Moreover, further innovation based on the protected technology may be stifled because, for instance, the length of the patent term is too long or the scope of the protection granted is too broad.
The length of the monopoly granted is one determinant of the strength of patent protection. Another is the scope of the patent. A broad patent is one that allows a right that goes considerably beyond the claimed invention itself. For example, a patent which claims a gene might only specify one use of that gene. But, under certain approaches to the scope of protection, the patentee will also have the rights to uses of the genetic information other than those disclosed in the patent including those discovered later by someone else. Broad patents can tend to discourage subsequent innovation by other researchers in the general area of the patent. In contrast, narrow claims will encourage others to ‘work around’ the patent, offering less restriction on related research by others. They may also tend to create stronger rights which are less vulnerable to challenge in the courts.[38] The licensing policy pursued by the patentee will also have an important effect on the dissemination of new technologies and the extent to which further research is affected by the granted rights.
The optimal degree of protection (where the social benefits are judged to exceed the social costs) will also vary widely by product and sector and will be linked to variations in demand, market structures, R&D costs and the nature of the innovative process. In practice IPR regimes cannot be tailored so precisely and therefore the level of protection afforded in practice is necessarily a compromise. Striking the wrong compromise - whether too much or too little - may be costly to society, especially in the longer term.
One underlying assumption is that there is a latent supply of innovative capacity in the private sector waiting to be unleashed by the grant of the protection that the IP system provides. That may be so in countries where there is substantial research capacity. But in most developing countries local innovation systems (at least of the kind established in developed countries) are weak. Even where such systems are stronger, there is often more capacity in the public than the private sectors.[39] Thus, in such contexts, the dynamic benefit from IP protection is uncertain. The patent system may provide an incentive but there may be limited local capacity to make use of it. Even when technologies are developed, firms in developing countries can seldom bear the costs of acquisition and maintenance of rights and, above all, of litigation if disputes arise.
Economists are also now very aware of what they call transactions costs. Establishing the infrastructure of an IPR regime, and mechanisms for the enforcement of IP rights, is costly both to governments, and private stakeholders. In developing countries, where human and financial resources are scarce, and legal systems not well developed, the opportunity costs of operating the system effectively are high. Those costs include the costs of scrutinising the validity of claims to patent rights (both at the application stage and in the courts) and adjudicating upon actions for infringement. Considerable costs are generated by the inherent uncertainties of litigation. These costs too need to be weighed against the benefits arising from the IP system.
Thus the value
of the patent system needs to be assessed in a balanced way, acknowledging that
it has both costs and benefits, and that the balance of costs and benefits is
likely to differ markedly in diverse circumstances.
Amongst academics, notably economists, IPRs have generally been viewed critically. Such rights necessarily involve restrictions on competition which may be to the detriment of consumers and the freedom of trade, and the question is whether these costs are outweighed by the incentives for research and invention. The quotations in Box 1.2 below reflect well the ambivalence that is widely expressed about the effects of the patent system in developed countries, and its impact on developing countries. This ambivalence has tended to strengthen as the IP system has embraced new technologies.
Box 1.2
Conclusions on the Value of the IP System
Edith Penrose in “The Economics of the International
Patent System” in 1951:
“Any country must lose if it grants monopoly
privileges in the domestic market which neither improve nor cheapen the goods
available, develop its own productive capacity nor obtain for its producers at
least equivalent privileges in other markets.
No amount of talk about the “economic unity of the world” can hide the
fact that some countries with little export trade in industrial goods and few,
if any, inventions for sale have nothing to gain from granting patents on
inventions worked and patented abroad except the avoidance of unpleasant
foreign retaliation in other directions.
In this category are agricultural countries and countries striving to
industrialise but exporting primarily raw materials…whatever advantages may
exist for these countries…they do not include advantages related to their own
economic gain from granting or obtaining patents on invention.”[40]
Fritz Machlup concluded after studying the US patent
system in 1958:
“If one does not know whether a system…is good or bad,
the safest “policy conclusion” is to muddle through – either with it, if one has
long lived with it, or without it, if one has lived without it. If we did not have a patent system, it would
be irresponsible, on the basis of our present knowledge of its economic
consequences, to recommend instituting one.
But since we have had a patent system for a long time, it would be
irresponsible, on the basis of our present knowledge, to recommend abolishing
it. This last statement refers to a
country such as the U.S. – not to a small country and not a predominantly
non-industrial country, where a different weight of argument might well suggest
another conclusion.”[41]
And another leading economist, Lester Thurow, wrote in
1997:
“In a global economy, a global system of intellectual property rights is needed. This system must reflect the needs both of countries that are developing and those that have developed. The problem is similar to the one concerning which types of knowledge should be in the public domain in the developed world. But the Third World’s need to get low cost pharmaceuticals is not equivalent to its need for low cost CDs. Any system that treats such needs equally, as our current system does, is neither a good nor a viable system.”[42]
A prominent academic lawyer, Larry Lessig, said of the
US in 1999:
“No doubt we are better off with a patent system than
without one. Lots of research and
invention wouldn't occur without the government's protection. But just because some protection is good,
more isn't necessarily better…There is growing skepticism among academics about
whether such state-imposed monopolies help a rapidly evolving market such as
the Internet…The question economists are now asking is whether expanded patent
protection will do any good. Certainly
it will make some people very rich, but that's different from improving a
market…Rather than unbounded protection, our tradition teaches balance and the
dangers inherent in overly strong intellectual property regimes. But balance in IP seems over for now. A
feeding frenzy has taken its place - not just in the field of patents, but in
IP generally…”[43]
And Jeffrey Sachs, an
eminent economist, said in 2002:
“…there is an opportunity
to re-think the intellectual property rights regime of the world trading system
vis-ŕ-vis the world’s poorest countries. In the Uruguay Round negotiation, the
international pharmaceutical industry pushed very hard for a universal coverage
of patent protection without considering the implications for the poorest
countries. There is little doubt that the new IPR arrangements can make it more
difficult for consumers in the poorest countries to access key technologies, as
we’ve seen vividly in the case of essential medicines. The countries
negotiating the new Doha round have already committed to re-examining the IPR
issue in light of public health priorities, and they are wise to do so. It also
may well be the case that the tightening of IPRs may slow the diffusion of
technology to the world’s poorest countries that has traditionally come through
copying and reverse engineering. Those hallowed pathways of technological
diffusion are increasingly being slowed, and the effects on the poorest
countries may be unduly hindered. This is an area for close observation, policy
attention, and continuing research."[44]
The rationale for copyright protection is not dissimilar to that of patents although historically greater weight has been given to the inherent rights of creative artists to receive fair remuneration for their works than to the incentive effects. Copyright protects the form in which ideas are expressed, not the ideas themselves. Copyright was and remains the basis for making the publishing of literary and artistic works an economic proposition by preventing copying. Unlike patents, copyright protection does not require registration or other formalities (although this was not always the case).
As with patents, the trade-off for society is between the incentive offered to creators of literary and artistic works and the restrictions this places on the free flow of protected works. But, unlike patents, copyright in principle protects the expression of ideas, and not the ideas as such, which may be used by others. And it only prevents the copying of that expression, not independent derivation. The central issue for developing countries concerns the cost of access to physical or digital embodiments of the protected works, and the approach taken to enforcement of copyright protection.
As with patents, there are normally exceptions in law where the rights of owners are moderated in the wider public interest, known in some countries as “fair use” provisions (for example in the US), as “fair dealing” in the UK tradition, and exceptions to the reproduction right in the European tradition.[45] It is the issue concerning the cost of access, and the interpretation of “fair use”, that is particularly critical for developing countries, made more so by the extension of copyright to electronic material, and to software.
Copyright protects works for much longer than patents but does not protect against independent derivation of the work in question. Under TRIPS copyright allows a minimum of fifty years after the death of the author, but most developed countries and several developing countries have increased this to 70 years or more. While the main reason for the extension of copyright has been pressure from the copyright industries (notably the film industry in the US), there is no clear economic rationale for copyright protection being so much longer than that for patents. Indeed, the rate of technical change has led in several industries to a shorter effective product life (for example, successive editions of software programmes) which point to longer copyright protection being redundant. The successive increases in the period of copyright protection have given rise to concern in some quarters. This year the US Supreme Court is hearing a case that challenges the 1998 Copyright Term Extension Act on the grounds that it violates the Constitution which specifies that protection must be for “limited Times”. In addition, it is asserted that an extension of protection granted for a work that already exists can have no incentive effect, and also violates the quid pro quo requirement in the Constitution that monopoly rights are provided in exchange for public benefits.[46]
As with patents, a key issue for developing countries is whether the gains to be elicited from the incentives provided by copyright outweigh the increased costs associated with the restrictions on use that flow from copyright. Although there are exceptions, such as India’s film or software industry, most developing countries are net importers of copyrighted material, just as they are net importers of technologies. Since copyright does not need registration or other formalities, once a country has copyright laws in place, the impact of copyright is more ubiquitous than in the case of patents. Software, textbooks, and academic journals are key items where copyright is a determining factor in pricing and access, and which are also essential ingredients in education and other spheres crucial to the development process. For instance, a reasonable selection of academic journals is far beyond the purchasing budgets of university libraries in most developing countries, and increasingly in developed countries as well.
The interaction of the Internet and copyright is an issue of particular and growing importance for developing countries. With printed media, there are provisions for “fair use” under copyright law, and the nature of the medium lends itself to multiple use either formally through libraries or informally through borrowing and browsing (as may be done in a bookshop before deciding to purchase). With material accessed through the Internet, the technology allows encryption and other means to exclude potential users even from browsing, unless they have paid the relevant charge. While the “philosophy” of the Internet has hitherto been about free access, increasingly sites with material of value are moving towards charging for use, or limiting access in other ways. Further, the DMCA in the US and Europe’s Database Directive have provisions that go well beyond what is required under TRIPS, and are held by many users to have shifted the balance of protection too far in favour of investors and originators of collections of data.
Thus, as with patents, there is a need for balance. Too much protection by copyright, by other forms of IP protection, or by technology may restrict the free flow of ideas on which the further progress of ideas and technology depends. For developing countries, affordable access to works essential for development such as educational materials and scientific and technical knowledge may be affected by unduly strong copyright rules.
There are several lessons that we can learn from history, particularly from the experience of the developed countries in the 19th century, and the emerging economies of East Asia in the last century.
First, historically IP regimes have been used by countries to further what they perceive as their own economic interests. Countries have changed their regimes at different stages of economic development as that perception (and their economic status) has changed. For instance between 1790 and 1836, as a net importer of technology, the US restricted the issue of patents to its own citizens and residents. Even in 1836, patents fees for foreigners were fixed at ten times the rate for US citizens (and two thirds as much again if one was British!). Only in 1861 were foreigners treated on an (almost wholly) non-discriminatory basis. In his Annual Report for 1858, the US Commissioner of Patents noted:
“It is a fact, as significant as it is deplorable,
that of the 10,359 inventions shown to have been made abroad during the last
twelve months, but forty-two have been patented in the US. The exorbitant fees
exacted of the foreigner, and the severity of the offensive discrimination
established to his prejudice, afford a sufficient explanation of the result…it
might well be concluded that the government of this country regarded an
invention made beyond the seas as something intrinsically dangerous, if not
noxious, the introduction of which it is morally just and politically wise to
burden with taxation, just as you would thus burden the importation of some
foreign poisonous drug. There is a loftier view of this question, and one
deemed more in harmony with the progressive spirit of the age -- a view which
hails the fruits of the inventive genius, in whatever clime matured, as the
common property of the world, and gives them cordial welcome as the common
blessings of the race to whose amelioration they are devoted.”[47]
Until 1891, US copyright protection was restricted to US citizens but various restrictions on foreign copyrights remained in force (for example, printing had to be on US typesets) which delayed US entry to the Berne Copyright Convention until as late as 1989, over 100 years after the UK. It is for this reason that some readers may remember purchasing books which had on the cover the words: “For copyright reasons this edition is not for sale in the U.S.A.”
Until the adoption of the Paris Convention (on protecting industrial property) in 1883, and its 1886 Berne counterpart (on literary and artistic works) countries’ ability to tailor the nature of their regimes to their own circumstances was unconstrained. Even then, the rules of these Conventions exhibited considerable flexibility. The Paris Convention allowed countries to exclude fields of technology from protection and to determine the length of protection afforded under patents. It also permitted revocation of patents, and compulsory licences[48] to remedy abuses.
Secondly, numerous countries have at times exempted various kinds of invention in certain sectors of industry from patent protection. Often, the law has restricted patents on products confining protection to processes for their production. Typically these sectors have been foodstuffs, pharmaceuticals and chemicals, based on the judgement that no monopoly should be granted over essential goods, and that there is more to be gained by encouraging free access to foreign technology, than by potentially stimulating invention in domestic industry. This approach was adopted by many countries which are now developed in the 19th Century, and for some until late in the 20th Century, and also in the East Asian countries (such as Taiwan and Korea) until relatively recently. However, TRIPS now forbids discrimination in the grant of patent protection in respect of different fields of technology.
Thirdly, intellectual property, and patents in particular, have often been politically contentious. Between 1850 and 1875, a debate raged in Europe, both in academic and political circles, on whether the patent system was a blight on free trade principles or the best practical means of stimulating inventions. John Stuart Mill took the latter view:
“…an exclusive privilege, of temporary duration is
preferable [as a means of stimulating invention]; because it leaves nothing to
anyone’s discretion; because the reward conferred by it depends upon the
invention’s being found useful, and the greater the usefulness, the greater the
reward; and because it is paid by the very persons to whom the service is
rendered, the consumers of the commodity.”[49]
In essence, this remains the case for the system today – a relatively inexpensive way (at least for governments, in so far as they are not purchasers of the goods) to provide an incentive for invention with a reward proportionate to the use subsequently made of it.[50]
Opposition to patent protection was advanced on various grounds but was summed up in the words of the Economist in 1851:
“The privileges granted to inventors by patent laws
are prohibitions on other men, and the history of inventions accordingly teems
with accounts of trifling improvements patented, that have put a stop, for a
long period, to other similar and much greater improvements…The privileges have
stifled more inventions than they have promoted…Every patent is a prohibition
against improvements in a particular direction, except by the patentee, for a
certain number of years; and, however, beneficial that may be to him who
receives the privilege, the community cannot be benefited by it…On all
inventors it is essentially a prohibition to exercise their faculties; and in
proportion as they are more numerous than one, it is an impediment to the
general advancement…”[51]
Again, this clearly illustrates a theme that recurs in current discussions. If the system protects one set of inventions, can it avoid deterring those who seek to make improvements upon the first?
Foreshadowing the debates concerning TRIPS, the 19th Century argument was also related to the free trade controversy in that the patent system, by conferring monopolies, was seen by some as a contravention of free trade principles. Moreover there was self-interest at work. In Switzerland in the 1880s, industrialists did not want a patent law because they wished to continue to use the inventions of foreign competitors. This opposition was maintained in spite of the fact that the Swiss were enthusiastic patentees in other countries themselves. And because Switzerland had low tariffs, they feared that those competitors would take out patents in Switzerland and then drive out Swiss competition under their protection.
Switzerland did eventually adopt a patent law, with various exclusions and safeguards, not because most Swiss thought there was any net benefit to be had from allowing foreign patents, but because Switzerland came under intense pressure, particularly from Germany, to do so and did not wish to invite retaliation from other countries.[52] Safeguards adopted included provisions for compulsory working[53] and compulsory licensing which enabled the government to enforce production in Switzerland by one means or another, if it so desired. In addition, chemicals and textile dyeing were excluded from patent protection. Elsewhere in Europe the proponents of the patent system also largely won the argument, just as the free trade movement waned in the face of the Great Depression in Europe. Only in Holland did the movement against patents wholly succeed, and from 1869 until 1912 no patents were issued there.[54]
Fourthly, the best examples in the recent history of development are the countries in East Asia which used weak forms of IP protection tailored to their particular circumstances at that stage of their development. Throughout the critical phase of rapid growth in Taiwan and Korea between 1960 and 1980, during which their economies were transformed, both countries emphasised the importance of imitation and reverse engineering[55] as an important element in developing their indigenous technological and innovative capacity. Korea adopted patent legislation in 1961, but the scope of patenting excluded foodstuffs, chemicals and pharmaceuticals. The patent term was only 12 years. It was only in the mid-1980s, particularly as a result of action by the US under Section 301 of its 1974 Trade Act, that patent laws were revised, although they did not yet reach the standards to be set under TRIPS. A similar process took place in Taiwan. In India, the weakening of IP protection in pharmaceuticals in its 1970 Patent Act[56] is widely considered to have been an important factor in the subsequent rapid growth of its pharmaceutical industry, as a producer and exporter of low cost generic medicines[57] and bulk intermediates.[58]
The general lesson history shows us is that countries have been able to adapt IPR regimes to facilitate technological learning and promote their own industrial policy objectives. Because policies in one country impinge on the interests of others, there has always been an international dimension to debates on IP. The Paris and Berne Conventions recognised this dimension, and the desirability of reciprocity, but allowed considerable flexibility in the design of IP regimes. With the advent of TRIPS, a large part of this flexibility has been removed. Countries can no longer follow the path adopted by Switzerland, Korea or Taiwan in their own development. The process of technological learning, and of progressing from imitation and reverse engineering to establishing a genuine indigenous innovative capacity, must now be done differently from in the past.
Analysis of the available evidence on the impact of IPR regimes on developing, or developed countries is a complex task. As noted above, we do not wish to focus on IPRs as an end in themselves, but on how they can contribute to development and the reduction of poverty. We believe that a prerequisite for sustainable development in any country is the development of an indigenous scientific and technological capacity. This is necessary to allow countries to develop their own process of technological innovation, and to enable them to absorb effectively technologies developed abroad. It is obvious that the development of such capacity is dependent on a large number of elements. It requires an effective education system, particularly at the tertiary level and a network of supporting institutions and legal structures. It also requires the availability of financial resources, both public and private, to pursue technological development. There are many other factors that contribute to what are often known as “national systems of innovation”.
Viewed this way, the issue is whether IPRs can contribute to promoting effective national systems of innovation in principle and, given the wide existing variations in the indigenous scientific and technological capacity, how they can do so effectively in practice, taking account of the circumstances in particular countries. Moreover, since we are not just interested in the dynamic effect of IPRs in promoting innovation, but also the costs that IP protection imposes on society, particularly on poor people, we need to take account of these costs in considering the evidence and the value of any given IP system.
Much of the evidence about IPRs is either indirect or based on proxy measures. We cannot measure directly a country’s capacity for innovation (for example, we might commonly use R&D expenditures or innovations-related expenditures as a proxy). Nor can we directly measure the strength of patent protection in a country (although indices have been compiled using a mixture of proxies). The use of econometrics, which is used to try and isolate the independent effect of IPRs on economic variables, is often contested, particularly as to whether it demonstrates association rather than causation. For instance, some authorities argue that the absence of IP protection encourages technology transfer and technological learning (through copying and imitation). Others argue that IP protection is a mechanism which encourages technology transfer from abroad through direct investment or licensing, and the indirect effects are an effective means of technological learning. Determining where the truth lies can be difficult for policymakers.
Developing countries, taken as a whole, are net importers of technology, most of which is supplied by the developed countries. Organisations in developed countries own the overwhelming proportion of patent rights worldwide. Econometric models have been constructed to estimate what would be the global impact of applying the TRIPS agreement (i.e. globalising minimum standards for IP protection). The latest estimate, by the World Bank, suggests that most developed countries would be the major beneficiaries of TRIPS in terms of the enhanced value of their patents, with the benefit to the US estimated at an annual $19 billion.[59] Developing countries, and a few developed ones, would be the net losers. The country sustaining the largest loss in the study by the World Bank was Korea ($15 billion). Not too much should be read into the exact value of these figures, which depend on a number of debateable assumptions, but it can safely be said that the effect of applying patent rights globally will be to benefit very considerably the holders of patent rights, mainly in developed countries, at the expense of the users of protected technologies and goods in developing countries. Between 1991 and 2001, the net US surplus of royalties and fees (which mainly relate to IP transactions) increased from $14 billion to over $22 billion.[60] In 1999, figures from the World Bank indicate a deficit for developing countries for which figures are available of $7.5 billion on royalties and licence fees.[61]
That the extension of IPRs would tend to benefit the developed countries is not surprising and explains why pressure was applied by industry in developed countries for the adoption of TRIPS. But the calculations above only consider the cost side of the IPR equation for developing countries. If IPRs are to benefit developing countries that benefit will need to come through promoting invention and technological innovation, and thereby enhancing growth.
At the country level, there appears to be little economic research on developing countries that directly links the IPR regime to domestic innovation and development. An approach common to Germany, and the East Asian countries (including China), was the introduction of easily obtained utility models (or petty patents), which combined a lower standard of inventiveness, with registration rather than examination, and a shorter protection period.[62] When introduced in Germany, in 1891, these provided for three years of protection (renewable for a further three years) and by the 1930s, twice as many utility patents as examined patents were granted.[63] Studies of Japan’s patent system in the period 1960-1993 have suggested that utility models were more important than patents in stimulating productivity growth.[64] There is also some evidence relating innovation in particular sectors in Brazil and the Philippines to the availability of such utility models.[65] In Japan, the evidence suggests that a system of “weak” protection based on utility models and industrial designs facilitated incremental innovation by small enterprises, and the absorption and diffusion of technology. This was associated, as in Taiwan and Korea, with an absence of patent protection for chemical and pharmaceutical products. Japan introduced protection for the latter only in 1976.[66]
There is more evidence about the impact of patent protection in developed countries. It appears to indicate that large firms consider patent protection of considerable importance in particular sectors (for example pharmaceuticals) but that in many sectors they are not considered important determinants of innovation.[67] Moreover, patents seem to be hardly used by small and medium enterprises in most sectors in many developed countries, as a means of promoting their innovation, or as a source of useful technical information. An important exception is the biopharmaceutical sector where companies often view their patent portfolios as their most important business asset.[68] A recent large study in the UK concluded that “formal IP regimes are applicable only to a small proportion of business activity, such as large manufacturing companies.” Other informal methods of protection, and of obtaining technical information, were generally more effective for SMEs.[69]
The crucial question from our point of view is to what extent IPRs promote growth. The evidence we have reviewed does not suggest strong direct effects on economic growth in developing countries.[70] One recent study found that the more open (to trade) an economy, the more likely it was that patent rights would affect growth. According to this calculation in an open economy, stronger patent rights might increase growth rates by 0.66% per annum.[71] But there is some debate about causation because both openness to trade and the strength of the IPR regime tend to increase in any case with per capita income.
Other evidence suggests that the strength of patent protection increases with economic development, but that this does not occur until quite high levels of per capita income. Indeed, prior to the recent global strengthening of IP laws, there was a reasonably consistent observed relationship between the strength of IP rights and per capita income. At low levels of income, protection is quite high (reflecting past colonial influences) but then falls to a low point of weak protection at an income of about $2000 (at 1985 prices) per capita. This low point is maintained until a per capita income of nearly $8000 when the strength of protection begins to increase again. This association is not necessarily causal but it does indicate that until relatively high levels of per capita income, IPR protection is not a high priority in developing country policy.[72]
Maybe the simplest evidence of the impact of the IP system is how much it is used, particularly by nationals. The propensity to take out patents will reflect some judgement as to the benefits, albeit private rather than social benefits. In sub-Saharan Africa in 1998 (excluding South Africa), 35 patents were granted to residents compared to 741 for non-residents. By contrast in Korea, 35900 patents were issued to residents, compared to 16990 to non-residents. In the US, the corresponding figures were 80292 and 67228.[73]
The main conclusion seems to be that for those developing countries that have acquired significant technological and innovative capabilities, there has generally been an association with “weak” rather than “strong” forms of IP protection in the formative period of their economic development. We conclude therefore that in most low income countries, with a weak scientific and technological infrastructure, IP protection at the levels mandated by TRIPS is not a significant determinant of growth. On the contrary, rapid growth is more often associated with weaker IP protection. In technologically advanced developing countries, there is some evidence that IP protection becomes important at a stage of development, but that stage is not until a country is well into the category of upper middle income developing countries.[74]
Although the direct impact on growth is difficult to discern, much effort has been devoted to establishing the impact of changing IPR rights on trade and foreign investment. We do not find some of this work very helpful to our study. Much of it does not address the impact of IP rights on developing countries, but focuses instead on the question of how developed country exports and investment may be affected by strengthening IP rights in developing countries. These two approaches are not the same.
For instance, some studies show that stronger patent rights in developing countries would significantly increase imports from developed countries (or indeed other developing countries).[75] The argument is that some imports are a form of technology transfer (for example, high technology machinery imports have an independent impact on productivity). But strengthening IPRs is also particularly effective in increasing imports of low technology consumer items and is associated with the decline of indigenous industries based on imitation.[76] This effect is clearly a mixed blessing for a developing country. It may be that there is access to more high technology imports previously withheld for lack of IP protection but the costs may be very substantial in terms of lost output and employment, or even retarded growth. This issue is now a very real one in countries such as China. These studies also imply that countries with little technological capacity may experience reduced imports because the patent laws have the effect of increasing import prices on average, and hence reduce import capacity. Countries in the past have protected themselves against the possible adverse effects of increased imports on domestic industry through provisions relating to compulsory working of patents, as Switzerland did in the 19th century.
As regards the analyses of the impact on foreign investment, we have similar reservations. There is a considerable literature which discusses the extent to which stronger IPRs influence foreign investment, licensing behaviour and the transfer of technology. Much of this literature reaches only tentative conclusions, because of weaknesses in data or methodology.[77] Many of the studies pose the question, partly for reasons of data availability, in terms of how strengthening patents rights in developing countries will affect the investment, production and licensing behaviour of US multinationals in developing countries. For instance, one of the conclusions reached in a recent study, but it is typical of others working with similar datasets, is as follows:
“…these results suggest that if an average developing country were to
strengthen its patent index by one unit, local sales of US affiliates would
rise by…about 2% of average annual sales…a one-unit increase in the patent
index of the average developing economy would raise the asset stock of US
multinational affiliates by…about 16% of average asset stock.”[78]
For policymakers in a developing country, the framework and questions might be rather different. He or she would want to know, if IPRs were strengthened, whether that would be likely to affect economic growth, employment, investment and R&D in the private sector, access to foreign technology, the domestic innovation process, and exports (as well as imports). There is a paucity of studies that directly address these issues of critical importance to policymakers in developing countries, let alone reach definitive conclusions on the impact of IPRs.
What is clear from the literature is that strong IP rights alone provide neither the necessary nor sufficient incentives for firms to invest in particular countries. If this was the case, then large countries with high growth rates but weak IPR regimes would not have received large foreign investment inflows in the past and even now. This includes many of the East Asian and Latin American economies which have received the bulk of such flows.[79] If the question is addressed in terms of what factors are most important in determining foreign investment, it is quite common for IPRs to be omitted altogether. For instance, recent reports from international institutions and bodies on investment flows almost entirely fail to mention IPRs as a factor. These include, for instance, the World Bank’s report on Global Development Finance 2002,[80] and the Zedillo report on Financing for Development.[81] Similarly, a recent draft World Bank report on improving India’s investment climate makes no mention at all of the role of IPRs. [82]
As we have noted, there is some evidence that for particular industries (such as chemicals) and for particular activities (such as R&D) IPRs may be a significant factor in the decision by firms to invest.[83] But the investment decision is contingent on many factors. For most low technology industries, of the kind that less technologically advanced developing countries are likely to attract, IPRs are unlikely to be a relevant factor in the investment decision. Where technologies are more sophisticated, but relatively easy to copy, then IPRs may be – though not necessarily - a significant factor in investment decisions if a country has both the scientific capacity to copy and a sufficiently large market to justify the costs of patenting and enforcement and other relevant factors are favourable. In other cases, however, the introduction of patent protection has been associated, as noted above, with an increase in imports, rather than investment in local production. Finally, in high technology industries and for countries with sophisticated technological capabilities, technology owners may opt to license their technologies, protected by the IP regime, rather than invest directly in production. Thus strong rights may deter investment flows but facilitate technology transfer under licensing, which we return to in the next section.
We conclude from the existing studies the
following:
· There is some evidence that trade flows into developing countries are influenced by the strength of IP protection, particularly for those industries (often high technology) that are “IPR sensitive” (for example, chemicals and pharmaceuticals), but the evidence is far from clear.
·
These flows may contribute to
productive capability. But they may
also be at the expense of domestic output and employment in local “copying” and
other industries. Developing countries
with no or weak technological infrastructure, may be adversely affected by the
higher prices of importing IP protected goods.
·
The evidence that foreign investment
is positively associated with IP protection in most developing countries is
lacking.
· For more technologically advanced developing countries, IPRs may be important to facilitate access to protected high technologies, by foreign investment or by licensing.
· Achieving the right balance may be difficult for some countries such as India or China where some industries have the potential to benefit from IP protection, but the associated costs for industries that were established under weak IP regimes as well as consumers are potentially high.
· Most of the evidence concerning the role of IP in trade and investment relates to those developing countries which are more technologically advanced. For other developing countries, we conclude that any beneficial trade and investment effects are unlikely to outweigh the costs at least in the short and medium term.
TECHNOLOGY
TRANSFER
In a sense, the crucial issue in respect of IP is not whether it promotes trade or foreign investment, but how it helps or hinders developing countries to gain access to technologies that are required for their development. If a supplier of foreign technology licenses production to a domestic firm, rather than itself establishing manufacturing locally, less foreign investment will have been attracted. However, the overall result may be more beneficial to the domestic economy because of the indirect contribution to domestic technological capabilities. If high technology imports increase as a result of strengthening IP regimes, a transfer of technology may be achieved (for example, as embodied in capital goods), but there is no guarantee that the domestic economy will be capable of absorbing that technology as a basis for further innovation. Therefore the transfer of technology may not be sustainable. Rather, as we have seen, some countries may use weak IP regimes as a means of gaining access to foreign technologies and developing them using reverse engineering, thereby enhancing indigenous technological capacity. The implementation of TRIPS now restricts the ability of developing countries to follow this path.
But the determinants of effective technology transfer are many and various. The ability of countries to absorb knowledge from elsewhere and then make use and adapt it for their own purposes is also of crucial importance. This is a characteristic that depends on the development of local capacity through education, through R&D, and the development of appropriate institutions without which even technology transfer on the most advantageous terms is unlikely to succeed. The effective transfer of technology also often requires the transfer of “tacit” knowledge, which cannot be easily codified (for example, as in patent disclosures or instruction manuals). This is why even the best-designed programmes to foster national capacity for research which are funded by donors have not always been successful. Since many technologies of interest to developing countries are produced by organisations from developed countries, the acquisition of technology requires the ability to negotiate effectively based on an understanding of the particular area of technology. This process requires a determined approach on the part of the recipient of technology to acquire the necessary human capital and the appropriate institutions. Countries such as Korea started at a low level of technological expertise forty years ago, comparable to many low income countries today, but have now become innovators in their own right.
This aspect of the process of technology transfer is largely in the hands of developing countries themselves. But this does not mean that developed countries, or international policies more generally, cannot facilitate or hinder the process. The TRIPS agreement recognises in Article 7 that IPRs should contribute to the “transfer and dissemination of technology” but also, in Article 8, that measures may need to be taken to prevent the abuse of IPRs including practices that “adversely affect the international transfer of technology.” Article 40 includes provisions to prevent anti-competitive practices in contractual licences. And Article 66.2 obliges developed countries to provide incentives to their enterprises and institutions to promote technology transfer to least developed countries (LDCs) in order to “enable them to create a sound and viable economic base”. These provisions in TRIPS reflect some of the provisions in the draft International Code of Conduct on Technology Transfer, on which negotiations between developed and developing countries failed in the 1980s.[84]
Since then, the global economy has changed. Notably, economic policies around the world have shifted from import substitution and directed industrialisation behind high tariff barriers towards open market policies which emphasise the benefits to be gained through low tariffs, global competition and a less directive role for governments in economic development. The so-called knowledge-based industries, and trade in high technology products, have grown apace. The importance of R&D has increased and product life cycles have shortened. In this liberalised and competitive environment, firms in developing countries can no longer compete on the basis of importing “mature” technologies from developed countries and producing them behind tariff barriers. Firms are more wary of transferring technology in ways that may increase the competition they face.
Thus the problem is not so much now about obtaining more or less mature technologies on fair and balanced terms, but of accessing the sophisticated technologies that are required to be competitive in today’s global economy. TRIPS has strengthened the global protection offered to suppliers of technology, but there is no international framework to ensure that the transfer of technology takes place within a competitive framework which minimises the restrictive technology licensing practices with which the Code was concerned.
We are uncertain as to how this gap in the international framework could best be filled. Recommencing discussions on a Code of Conduct is not a viable option in the changed environment. But we do think encouraging and assisting them to build their own competition law regimes could better serve the interests of developing countries. The development of a framework for international competition policy has been discussed for some time in the WTO. We understand the reluctance of developing countries to embark down this path, but the development of national competition laws and effective international cooperation could act as a counterbalance to the aspects of the TRIPS agreement which have the effect of restricting competition globally, and inhibiting technology transfer in certain circumstances.
As regards TRIPS, the evidence suggests that the provisions in Article 66.2 have been ineffective. Developed countries do not appear to have taken additional measures to encourage technology transfer by their firms and institutions. Moreover, the fact that the article applies only to LDCs seems unduly restrictive. As noted above, these are likely to be countries for the most part with the least absorptive capacity. We do not therefore consider that Article 66.2 is the most appropriate way to address the entire issue of technology transfer to developing countries. Moreover some of the IPR provisions used historically to facilitate technology transfer, such as the use of compulsory working, have been significantly diluted under TRIPS. Since technology is mostly in private hands and TRIPS is principally concerned with the protection of IPRs, rather than technology transfer, we are unsure as to whether TRIPS, rather than the WTO more generally, is the right focus for a discussion on technology transfer.
We therefore welcome the establishment of the Working Group on Trade and Technology Transfer which will report to the WTO Ministerial Conference next year.[85] We suggest this includes consideration of whether the TRIPS agreement could be made to work better as one mechanism to promote technology transfer, and what measures might be desirable to ensure that the IPR system promotes, and does not hinder, technology transfer. However, we see the range of complementary measures that will be required to promote technology transfer as equally important.
Although most applied technology is privately owned, it is important to remember the extent to which public spending on basic and applied research supports the process of technological development. Developed country public research spending now often has the explicit objective of enhancing international competitiveness and increasingly, the results of such research may be patented, as we discuss in Chapter 6. Not only is research funding often tied to nationals, perhaps understandably, but also the benefits of such research may be restricted to nationals. For instance the law in the US restricts for the most part the licensing of publicly financed technologies to nationals, a policy for which the scientific and economic logic is less clear.[86]
Much
of the technology transfer agenda goes well beyond our brief but we think the
following measures need to be seriously considered:
·
Appropriate incentive policies in developed countries to promote
technology transfer, for instance tax breaks for companies that license
technology to developing countries.
·
Establishment of effective competition policies in developing
countries.
·
Making more public funds available to promote indigenous scientific
and technological capability in developing countries through scientific and
technological cooperation. For
instance, supporting the proposed Global Research Alliance[87]
between developing and developed country research institutions.
·
Commitments to ensure that the benefits of publicly funded research
are available to all.
· Commitments to ensure open access to scientific databases.
INTRODUCTION
The impact of intellectual property rules and practices on the health of poor people in developing countries has generated substantial controversy in recent years. Although this predated TRIPS,[88] and featured prominently in the TRIPS negotiations, impetus has been added by the coming into force of TRIPS, and the dramatic rise in the incidence of HIV/AIDS, particularly in developing countries. For the developed countries, the pharmaceutical industry was one of the main lobbyists for the global extension of IP rights.[89] For developing countries, a major concern was how the adoption of intellectual property regimes would affect their efforts to improve public health, and economic and technological development more generally, particularly if the effect of introducing patent protection was to increase the price and decrease the choice of sources of pharmaceuticals.
We are aware of the importance of effective patent protection for the industry most directly involved in discovering and developing new pharmaceuticals. Indeed, without the incentive of patents it is doubtful the private sector would have invested so much in the discovery or development of medicines, many of which are currently in use both in developed and developing countries. The pharmaceutical industry in developed countries is more strongly dependent on the patent system than most other industrial sectors to recoup its past R&D costs, to generate profits, and to fund R&D for future products. Successive surveys have shown that the pharmaceutical companies, more than any other sector, think patent protection to be very important in maintaining their R&D expenditures and technological innovation.[90] The industry understandably takes a close interest in the global application of IPRs, and generally resists the contention that they constitute a major barrier to access or a deterrent to development in developing countries. For instance, Sir Richard Sykes, the former Chairman of GSK, said in March this year:
“Few would argue with the need for IP protection in
the developed world, but some question whether it is appropriate to extend its
coverage to the developing world, which the TRIPS agreement is gradually
doing. As I have said, IP protection is
not the cause of the present lack of access to medicines in developing
countries. At Doha last November, WTO
members agreed to defer TRIPS implementation for the least developed countries
until 2016. I do not believe that TRIPS
will prevent other developing countries like Brazil and India from obtaining
access to the medicines they need. On
the other hand, I firmly believe that these countries have the capacity to
nurture research-based pharmaceutical industries of their own, as well as other
innovative industries, but this will only happen when they provide the IP
protection that is enshrined in TRIPS.
TRIPS needs to be recognised as an important industrial development tool
for developing countries.”[91]
That said, we are also fully aware of the concerns expressed by, and on behalf of, developing countries about the impact that such rights may have in those countries, particularly on prices of pharmaceuticals. If prices are raised, this will fall especially hard upon poor people, particularly in the absence of widespread provision for public health as exists in most developed countries. Thus others from many developing countries, and the NGO community, have argued the opposite:
“Why do developing countries object so strongly to
TRIPS? Its essential flaw is to oblige all countries, rich and poor, to grant
at least 20 years' patent protection for new medicines, thereby delaying
production of the inexpensive generic substitutes upon which developing-country
health services and poor people depend. And there is no upside: the increased
profits harvested by international drug firms from developing-world markets
will not be ploughed back into extra research into poor people's diseases - a
fact some companies will in private admit.”[92]
Our starting point in this analysis is that healthcare considerations must be the main objective in determining what IP regime should apply to healthcare products. IP rights are not conferred to deliver profits to industry except so that these can be used to deliver better healthcare in the long term. Such rights must therefore be closely monitored to ensure that they do actually promote healthcare objectives and, above all, are not responsible for preventing poor people in developing countries from obtaining healthcare.
A spur to much of the recent debate has been the HIV/AIDS pandemic, although the issue of access to medicines in developing countries goes much wider. It is particularly important not to allow the debate in this area to be influenced unduly by the HIV/AIDS experience, dramatic though it is. Apart from HIV/AIDS, which is the biggest single cause of mortality in developing countries, TB and malaria claim almost as many lives. Together all three diseases claimed nearly six million lives last year, and led to debilitating illness for millions more.[93] In addition, there are a number of less common diseases which are collectively important. These include, for instance, measles, sleeping sickness, leishmaniasis and Chagas disease.[94]
Each group of diseases presents different problems in respect of the development of cures and treatments, and the economics of the R&D process. For diseases prevalent in the developed world as well as developing countries, such as HIV/AIDS, cancer or diabetes, research in the private or public sector in the developed world may produce treatments that are also appropriate to the developing world. For these diseases, one would expect that the promise of strong IP protection in the developed world would act as a major incentive for investment in R&D. But it should be noted that some strains of HIV/AIDS in Africa, for example, are different from those in developed countries, so different treatments may need to be devised.
Where appropriate treatments already exist, access to them depends on affordability, and the availability of the health service infrastructure to support delivery. We regard the cost of pharmaceutical products as an important concern in developing countries because most poor people in developing countries pay for their own drugs, and state provision is normally selective and resource-constrained. This is generally not the case in the developed world where costs are mainly met by the state or through insurance schemes. Even so the cost of drugs is a controversial political issue in developed countries, for governments and for patients not covered by effective state or insurance schemes.[95] In developing countries, inadequacy of the infrastructure is an important problem, and may mean that even inexpensive medicines are not used, or that they may be misused and contribute to the emergence of drug resistant pathogens or a virus.
Again, HIV/AIDS provides a helpful illustration of the issues. The treatment of HIV with anti-retrovirals (ARVs), or drugs to treat opportunistic infections associated with the disease, raises the affordability issue acutely. The minimum annual costs of ARV therapies, even at deeply discounted or generic prices which do not cover R&D costs, far exceed the annual health expenditure per capita of most developing countries. Current per capita health expenditures in low income developing countries average $23 per year, but the most inexpensive ARV triple therapies are now just over $200 per year.[96] Thus, without extra funding for medicines and health delivery services, treatment for all those requiring it will remain unaffordable even at the cheapest generic prices. The World Health Organisation (WHO) estimates that fewer than 5% of those who require treatment for HIV/AIDS are receiving ARVs. Only about 230,000 of the 6 million estimated to be in need of such treatment in the developing world actually receive it, and nearly half of these people live in Brazil.[97]
Similar questions about affordability arise for treatments of other diseases. For example, TB and malaria are for the most part prevalent in developing countries, although there is a resurgence of TB in the developed world. It also needs to be remembered that TB is the leading cause of death among HIV-infected people, and about one third of them are co-infected with TB.[98] For these diseases, and for diseases exclusive to the developing world, the issue is both how to mobilise resources for R&D from the private and public sectors for new medicines, and having developed them to ensure access for those that need them.
The latter point is one of the most crucial questions concerning healthcare in developing countries. How can the resources necessary to develop new drugs and vaccines for diseases that predominantly affect developing, rather than developed, countries be generated when the ability to pay for them is so limited? Even when there is a developed country market from which these resources can be recovered through high prices, how can the affordability of these drugs in developing countries be secured? How can conflicts between the two objectives – covering R&D costs and minimising consumer costs – be resolved? As with technological development more generally, does the IP system have a role to play in stimulating the capacity of developing countries themselves to develop and produce drugs that they or other developing countries need?
This is the context in which we need to consider the role that IPRs could play in helping to address these dilemmas. It is not for us to consider in any depth the wide range of factors that affect the health of poor people or the quality of health services in developing countries. These have been discussed at some length in the recent report of the WHO Commission on Macroeconomics and Health (CMH).[99] The CMH concluded that a large injection of additional public funds into health services, infrastructure and research was required to address the health needs of developing countries. It took the view that patent protection offered little incentive for research on developing country diseases, in the absence of a significant market.[100] As regards access to medicines, it favoured coordinated action to establish a system of differential pricing[101] in favour of developing countries backed up, if necessary, by the more extensive use of compulsory licensing.[102]
Those conclusions are relevant for our current task. It is our role to indicate in greater detail how changes in intellectual property rules and practices could contribute to better health for poor people, while being fully aware that such changes have to be complemented by the range of actions suggested by the CMH.
We do this by considering three main questions:
· How does the intellectual property system contribute to the development of drugs and vaccines that are needed by poor people?
· How does the intellectual property system affect the access of poor people to drugs and availability?
· What does this imply for intellectual property rules and practices?
Research Incentives
It is estimated that less than 5% of the money spent worldwide on pharmaceutical R&D is for diseases that predominantly affect developing countries.[103] Pharmaceutical research by the private sector is driven by commercial considerations and if the effective demand in terms of market size is small, even for the most common diseases such as TB and malaria, it is often not commercially worthwhile to devote significant resources to addressing the needs. In 2002, the world drug market is valued at $406 billion, of which the developing world accounts for 20%, and low income developing countries very much less.[104] In many pharmaceutical companies, research objectives are set by reference to threshold returns. We were given to understand that the large pharmaceutical companies are unwilling to pursue a line of research unless the potential outcome is a product with annual sales of the order of $1 billion. Given that private companies have to be primarily responsible to their shareholders, this necessarily leads to a research agenda led by the market demand in the markets of the developed world, rather than by the needs of poor people in the developing world, and thus a focus mainly on non-communicable disease.
Regardless of the intellectual property regime prevailing in developing countries, in reality there is little commercial incentive for the private sector to undertake research of specific relevance to the majority of poor people living in low income countries. Accordingly, little such work is done by the private sector. Total pharmaceutical R&D in the private sector has more than doubled in the last decade to an estimated $44 billion in 2000.[105] Exactly what proportion of this is directed to diseases afflicting mainly developing countries is difficult to determine. However it has been estimated that of 1393 drugs approved between 1975 and 1999, only 13 were specifically indicated for tropical diseases.[106] Where diseases are common to both developed and developing countries, the picture is different. Thus, there is significant private sector R&D on HIV/AIDS. This contrasts with the limited work on tuberculosis and malaria, and virtually none on diseases such as sleeping sickness.[107] As regards HIV/AIDS, there are now 64 approved drugs in the US for treatment of the disease and opportunistic infections, and 103 in development.[108]
In the case of the public sector, such as the National Institutes of Health (NIH) in the US or Medical Research Councils (MRCs) in other developed countries, the situation is little different because their research priorities are principally determined by domestic considerations. Public sector spending on health research was estimated to be $37 billion in 1998, of which $2.5 billion was spent in low and middle income developing countries.[109] In 2001 the US National Institutes of Health (NIH) alone accounted for over $20 billion. In addition, charitable foundations are estimated to have spent $6 billion.[110] The WHO’s Special Programme for Research and Training in Tropical diseases (known as TDR) receives only about $30 million annually. The exact proportion of public sector spending on diseases relevant to developing countries has not been authoritatively estimated, but seems unlikely to be higher than 10%.[111] This situation is now being addressed through the WHO, the Global Forum for Health Research, the initiative of Médecins Sans Frontičres (MSF) on drugs for neglected diseases, additional funding by foundations and the development of several public-private partnerships to address specific diseases.[112] But the overall level of funding for these new efforts is still very modest in relation to the scale of the problem and global R&D expenditure of about $75 billion, and the outcome uncertain.
So what role does IP protection play in stimulating R&D on diseases prevalent in developing countries? All the evidence we have examined suggests that it hardly plays any role at all, except for those diseases where there is a large market in the developed world (for example, diabetes or heart disease). There is some weak evidence related to an increase in indicators of research activity in malaria since TRIPS was agreed, but the relation between cause and effect is not at all clear.[113] The heart of the problem is the lack of market demand sufficient to induce the private sector to commit resources to R&D. Therefore, we believe that presence or absence of IP protection in developing countries is of at best secondary importance in generating incentives for research directed to diseases prevalent in developing countries.
Thus this research may be inadequate in quantity because of inadequate effective demand from developing countries where the disease is heavily concentrated. Moreover research, particularly on vaccines, may require tackling characteristics of diseases specific to developing countries, where the solution for the developed world may not address the problem in the developing world. For example, the majority of HIV vaccines are being developed for genetic profiles of subtype B, prevalent in developed countries, but most AIDS sufferers in developing countries are types A and C. Vaccine research for HIV is also particularly scientifically challenging because of the way the virus evades the body’s natural immune responses, and the way it mutates.[114] Malaria vaccine research is also challenging, because of the size and diversity of the malaria parasite, and the complexity of its mutations.[115] Thus, for the private sector, vaccine research is a high risk/low return investment, particularly in relation to disease types prevalent in developing countries. The market tends to undervalue the social returns from vaccines, more than is the case for treatments.[116] In the case of malaria, the market demand is dominated by prophylaxis for travellers from developed countries, rather than vaccines which would be of greater relevance to sufferers in the developing world.
In respect of TB, where there are an estimated eight million people in developing countries that have the disease, no new class of anti-TB drug has been developed for over 30 years. Current treatments require drug courses of 6 months or more. A drug that produced the same effect in two months could have a dramatic impact in helping to control the disease globally. The scientific challenge of producing such a medicine is significant because of the characteristics of the disease.[117] A recent report by the Global Alliance for TB Drug Development has estimated that based on market demand (both private and public, including from developed countries) there might in fact be a respectable financial rate of return on the estimated cost of developing a new and improved drug. Nevertheless it is still not considered that IP protection, and favourable economics, will induce investment without considerable public sector involvement.[118] The current business model of the research-based pharmaceutical companies is such that research expenditure and profit generation are dependent on the sales of a few “blockbuster” drugs (normally with sales in excess of $1 billion per annum), which help finance the high percentage of failures in the R&D process.[119] But these companies have the freedom to pursue promising avenues wherever they may lead (for example, treatment for a disease or condition not previously envisaged). The economics of research for a specific treatment for a particular disease have to be very favourable to induce significant research effort.
Some, such as Sir Richard Sykes above, have argued that providing IP protection in developing countries with significant scientific and technical skills will help to increase the amount of research devoted to developing country diseases. Evidence on this is lacking because most of the relevant countries have only just introduced TRIPS-compliant laws, or are yet to do so. But we see no reason why firms with research capability in developing countries should respond to global IP and market incentives significantly differently from those based in developed countries. There is some evidence for this behaviour from firms in countries such as India.[120] The reality is that private companies will devote resources to areas where an optimal return can be made. Moreover, widely supported moves to establish differential pricing would reduce margins to reward R&D in developing countries, further undermining any incentive for additional research on developing country diseases.
In short we do not think that the globalisation of IP protection will make a significant contribution to increasing R&D expenditure by the private sector relevant to the treatment of diseases that particularly affect developing countries. The only feasible way to do this is by increasing the quantity of international aid resources devoted to such R&D. The CMH recommended an additional $3 billion annually to be spent on R&D through a new Global Health Research Fund, existing mechanisms and public-private partnerships.[121]
How increased publicly funded research should be directed requires careful consideration. It should not act as a form of subsidy to the existing pharmaceutical industry, although the industry certainly has an important part to play. The opportunity should be taken to build up the capacity of developing countries themselves to undertake R&D on treatments for those diseases which particularly affect them. In the technologically more advanced developing countries, such research can be highly cost-effective. For instance, General Electric has established its second largest R&D Centre in the world in India, employing about 1000 PhDs and 27 other global firms set up R&D centres in India between 1997 and 1999.[122] Thus research could be conducted with the active participation of selected research institutions and companies in developing countries, taking advantage of the human resources available in such countries and lower R&D costs. The institutional structure of for such funding also needs thought. The CGIAR[123] network of agricultural research institutes (which we discuss in Chapter 3) is one model. More promising in this context might be a network of public-private partnerships in developing countries, taking advantage of the concentration of research resources in public sector institutions but also the opportunity to build research capacity in the private sector. In particular the arrangements for intellectual property arising from such research need to be such that access by the poor to the products of research is ensured as much as possible.
Public
funding for research on health problems in developing countries should be
increased. This additional funding
should seek to exploit and develop existing capacities in developing countries
for this kind of research, and promote new capacity, both in the public and
private sectors.
Although IP may not have much to contribute in generating additional research relevant to poor people, it is clear to us that there are important issues about the impact of the patent system on the research process. While patent protection provides an incentive for R&D, the patenting of intermediate technologies (particularly gene-based ones) required in the research process may actually create disincentives for researchers in terms of accessing, or unwittingly infringing patents on, technologies they need.[124] This is an area where patent practices in the developed world can impinge directly on what research is done for people in the developing world, and there are implications for the type of patent regimes that developing countries adopt. The IP arrangements in public-private partnerships also give rise to important questions of managing IP to benefit poor people. We consider these questions in Chapter 6.
ACCESS TO
MEDICINES FOR POOR PEOPLE
The purpose of patents, as we have noted, is to provide a temporary monopoly to rights holders as a stimulus to inventions and their commercialisation. However, it should also be noted that the monopoly right provided by a patent normally only excludes others from making, using or selling that particular invention. It does not prevent competition from other drugs, patented or not, that address the same medical conditions. Nevertheless, other things being equal there is a presumption that the producer of a patented product, through the ability to exclude copies, will attempt to earn a monopoly profit and charge higher prices than would otherwise be the case. That, indeed, is the basis of the system. The bargain with society is precisely that the benefits to society generated by the extra innovation induced (for example, a lifesaving drug which might not exist but for the patent system) should exceed the extra cost of the product.
Given that in developing countries most people are poor and that patent protection can increase prices, it is necessary to examine with particular care the arguments put forward by some that patents in developing countries are not likely significantly to affect access to pharmaceuticals subject to patent protection. There are two grounds on which this argument is made. First, because patents are not always sought in some – especially smaller - developing countries, they cannot be a significant problem in accessing medicines. Secondly, even if they are sought, either this is not a determining factor in pricing or there are other overriding factors that prevent access to drugs by the poor.
Prevalence
of Patenting
It is true that, although patent protection for pharmaceutical products is available in most developing countries, multinational companies have not patented their products in all of them. This is normally the case for countries with small markets and limited technological capacity. Companies may take the view that it is not worth the expense of obtaining and maintaining protection when the potential market is small, and the risk of infringement low. For instance, a recent study in 53 African countries found that the extent of patenting of 15 important antiretroviral drugs was 21.6% of the possible total.[125] In 13 countries there were no patents on these medicines at all. The conclusion was drawn that, because the patenting rate was so small, patents “generally do not appear to be a substantial barrier to…treatment in Africa today”, although it was recognised that there would be an issue when TRIPS came into force for all WTO members.[126]
Although the overall prevalence of patents found in the study is relatively low in aggregate, it is perhaps surprising that it is not lower, given the very low treatment rates, small markets, and the fact that few countries are capable of producing generic copies. The prevalence of patents is very much higher in countries where there is a substantial market, and technological capacity. Thus in South Africa (which alone counts for over 17% of Africa’s HIV cases) 13 of the 15 drugs are patented. There are 6-8 patents for these drugs in Botswana, Gambia, Ghana, Kenya, Malawi, Sudan, Swaziland, Uganda, Zambia and Zimbabwe, which together account for another 31% of HIV cases in sub-Saharan Africa.[127]
The industry points out that the prevalence of patenting is very much lower, or nil, for a wide range of drugs to treat other diseases. Until the latest revision this year, less than 5% of the drugs on the WHO Essential Drugs List were patented.[128] An industry survey indicated that 94% of countries surveyed had no patents on TB and malaria drugs, and no country has patents on all the relevant drugs for these diseases. There were no patents at all on drugs for trypanosomiasis or diarrhoeal diseases.[129] The argument advanced by industry is that even where there is no patent protection, the drugs are still not available.[130] For instance, even where vaccines are available for various common diseases and cheap (for example, less that $1 for a polyvalent vaccine), WHO’s Expanded Programme of Immunisation (EPI), in spite of undoubted successes, still fails to reach many children who could benefit.
This is of course true, but it does not follow that the patent system has no adverse effects. Even if patents do not exist for particular products and countries, the patent system may still have an effect on access to medicines. Most low income developing countries have to rely on imports for their supplies. The existence of patents in potential supplier countries may allow the patentee to prevent supplies being exported to another country, particularly through controls on distribution channels. This is another reason why companies may selectively patent in countries such as South Africa because it is a potential supplier to its poorer neighbours in the rest of Southern Africa (or indeed elsewhere). At present, importing countries where there is no patent protection have the option of importing supplies from generic companies, principally in India, because India need not have pharmaceutical product protection until 2005. But thereafter, under TRIPS, new drugs and those for which patent applications were submitted after 1994 will be patentable, and the opportunity for these imports will diminish correspondingly over time. However, it should be noted that all existing drugs produced as generics in India or elsewhere will continue to be available for export provided, of course, they are not patented in the importing country. We return to this issue below in our discussion of policy options.
Patents and Prices
The importance of prices of medicines to poor consumers in developing countries is perhaps obvious. But it is worth emphasising that if a sick person has to pay more for a pharmaceutical product as a result of a patent, it means that he or she will have less to spend on other essentials of life such as food or shelter. Alternatively, foregoing the medicine because it is unavailable or unaffordable may result in long term ill health, or death. That is why it is essential to consider the impact of the introduction of an IP regime on prices, while recognising that prices are affected by many factors. These include purchasing power, competition and market structure, responsiveness of demand to price and government price controls and regulations.
It is particularly difficult to observe directly and isolate the impact of introducing patents in developing country markets. In part we have to rely on econometric models to simulate the impact of introducing patent protection, and in part the experience of developed countries where generic producers compete with research-based ones.
There is extensive evidence from developed countries that prices fall quite steeply as soon as drugs go off patent, assuming there are generic competitors. The price fall seems to be greater the more generic competitors enter the market. Governments can encourage price reductions by facilitating the early entry of generic producers into the market. For instance, the 1984 Drug Price Competition and Patent Term Restoration Act in the US (known as the Hatch-Waxman Act) did precisely that, resulting in the share of generics in prescriptions dispensed rising from 19% in 1984 to 47% in 2000.[131] In other developed countries, such as the UK, the generic share of the market is often much higher. Pharmaceutical companies have also brought or defended expensive court actions to delay or prevent generic entry, and to protect or extend a monopoly on a best selling drug.[132] Correspondingly, we must remember that generic producers are governed by market incentives just as the research-based industry, and that it is necessary to encourage competition within the generic industry if lower drug prices are to be achieved. A recent study in the US found that prices fall when generic competition enters the market but at least five generic competitors are necessary to push prices down to a minimum.[133] The number of competitors entering the market, and the speed with which they do so, will depend on the expected profits. A crucial finding is that the full benefits of competition will only be felt at quite large market sizes – in smaller markets fewer generic firms will consider the market worth entering and prices to consumers will be higher. This is very relevant to the position of developing countries, as discussed below.
Developing countries can also limit the costs of the patent system for their population by facilitating generic entry and generic competition. But in most cases their options are severely limited by the small size of their markets and lack of indigenous technological, productive and regulatory capacity. It is this lack of capacity to create a competitive environment for both patented and generic products that makes the existence of patents more contentious than in developed markets with greater capacity to enforce a strongly pro-competitive regulatory environment.
International comparisons show that copies of drugs patented elsewhere are much cheaper in markets which do not offer patent protection. The Indian market, where there is no product protection, is the lowest priced in the world. One of our studies indicated that for 12 drugs covering a range of conditions US prices range from four to 56 times the price of equivalent formulations in India, and yet still a large number of people in India cannot obtain access to them.[134]
However, studies of multinational company pricing policies (mainly for ARVs) indicate that until recently there was remarkably little correlation between the price of the same drug and a country’s per capita income. This correlation is expected on theoretical grounds because companies should be able to make more profits by charging low prices in low income markets and high prices in high income markets (known as differential pricing), than by charging a uniform global price. But prices have appeared to vary more or less randomly between countries. Some developing countries paid more than US prices and some less. At best there was a very weak relationship between wholesale drug prices and per capita income.[135] The actual price to the patient is complicated by import duties, local tariffs, taxes and wholesaler profits.[136]
In the last two years this situation may have changed somewhat as some companies have drastically lowered prices offered in response to international pressure, principally from NGOs, and potential competition from generic manufacturers, particularly from India. For instance, between July 2000 and April 2002 the annual cost of a branded triple therapy ARV combination fell from over $10000 to just over $700 for selected groups of consumers. By then the lowest generic price for this combination had fallen to $209.[137]
But to estimate the impact of introducing patent regimes anew in developing countries, it is necessary to use econometric models. There is a small but growing literature, that relates almost entirely to lower and middle income developing countries which already have significant pharmaceutical industries. This literature demonstrates that the introduction of patent regimes into such developing countries has, or is predicted to have, the effect of raising prices. The estimates range widely depending on the drugs and countries being considered – from 12% to over 200%, but even the lower estimates imply very substantial costs for consumers.[138] The range of estimates is indicative of the degree of uncertainty about the dynamic effect of introducing patents, and suggests that the outcome will be very much determined by market structure and demand, in particular the degree of competition.
There is also considerable evidence that consumption of medicines is sensitive to price. One study in Uganda estimated that reducing the price of an ARV triple therapy from $6000 per annum to $600 per annum would increase the demand for treatment from 1000 to 50000 patients if associated with relatively modest investments in treatment infrastructure (of $4-6 million).[139] Another study, also in Uganda, indicated that price cuts arising from discounts by brand name companies, further lowered by the import of generic equivalents, increased the number of patients being treated threefold between 2000 and 2001.[140] A global econometric study estimated that the effect of eliminating patents in a cross-section of developing countries would be to increase access to ARVs by 30%, albeit from the very low existing level.[141]
The impact of introducing patent systems is likely to be most strongly felt in the group of countries that have developed strong generic industries, with a degree of competition that has kept prices low. There is evidence from some countries that the introduction of patents (for example in Italy in 1978) or strengthening the regime, as in Canada in the 1990s, by increasing the market power of foreign multinationals, will result in the consolidation and restructuring of the domestic industry. This may entail significant costs to the consumer by reducing the degree of competition in the market and increasing imports. Whether these costs may be offset by other benefits (for example, a boost to local research) is much debated. In Italy and Canada, two developed countries, the evidence is mixed.[142] In Italy multinational companies took over many local companies, exports of generic drugs declined and imports of patented drugs increased. There was little evidence of increased R&D. In Canada, there is evidence of a significant rise in R&D, partly as a result of a deal struck with the multinational manufacturers and tax credits allowed under the Income Tax Act (1987), but R&D is focused on preclinical and clinical trials and improvement of manufacturing processes rather than on the development of new molecules.[143] In both countries price controls were used to limit price increases on patented products.
In developing countries with strong generic industries, the outlook is also uncertain. On the one hand, manufacturers of mainly generic drugs are likely to be adversely affected by the introduction of patent protection, and also consumers and governments who will need to pay more for drugs that receive patent protection. On the other hand, producers who are developing a research capability, or who may be able to obtain licences from multinational companies, may perceive benefits from patent protection. These conflicting impacts explain why the introduction of patent protection in India is so controversial. Sections of the Indian pharmaceutical industry support the introduction of patent protection, and are gearing up their research in anticipation of its introduction, while other sections strongly oppose it. And, of course, it is controversial with consumer groups and NGOs.
More generally, as the TRIPS agreement is implemented, the supply of generic copies of new drugs will be prevented. At present, the threat of international competition from generic suppliers of copies of patented drugs is a restraining factor on the prices that can be charged in countries with no patent regimes, and to a lesser extent in countries with patent regimes where there is a credible threat of compulsory licensing. When all producer countries have patent laws, generics will increasingly be limited to older off-patent drugs. This will be no different from the current situation in developed countries, but developing countries will still find it difficult to afford new on-patent medicines. Means will need to be found, within the patent system and outside it, to generate the competitive environment that will help to offset the adverse price effect of patents on developing country consumers. We consider below some of the measures that need to be considered to ensure that the patent system supports a country’s right to protect human health and to promote access to medicines, in line with the Doha Declaration on TRIPS and Public Health (hereafter Doha Declaration – see Box 2.1).
It is argued, for instance by the pharmaceutical industry, that the most important constraints to access to medicines in developing countries, are not patent protection but the lack of spending on healthcare in developing countries, and the absence of a suitable health infrastructure to administer medicines safely and efficaciously. Improper administration may contribute to the development of drug resistance, apart from being ineffective. In the case of HIV, where the virus mutates readily, wide distribution of ARVs without the development of adequate infrastructure may contribute to the emergence of drug resistance.[144] It is also argued that generic versions of patented drugs may be of sub-standard quality, or even hazardous.[145]
A report by the US pharmaceutical industry association says:
“Handicapped by
limited financial resources, these nations’ ability to contain AIDS and address
a host of other killer diseases is compromised by inadequate infrastructure,
cultural barriers to care, and mismanaged health care systems. Some developing
countries also are hampered by political leadership that lacks the will to
confront or even acknowledge their nation’s health care needs.”[146]
Other than patents, there are a number of factors that affect drug prices, such as tariffs and other forms of indirect taxation.[147] It can appear perverse to complain about the price impact of patents, while ignoring other policies under national control that have a similar effect. Thus it is important that national tax systems operate in a way that supports public health policies, just as the patent system should.
In order to help allay concerns about delivery mechanisms for AIDS drugs, the WHO has this year produced the first treatment guidelines for using ARVs in poor settings and issued a list of manufacturers and products (including eleven ARVs) which meet WHO quality standards as suppliers to UN agencies. The list currently includes both producers of patented products and a number of generic versions of these products including, so far, two Indian suppliers. In addition the WHO has this year included for the first time twelve ARVs for the treatment of AIDS (two were already there but for the treatment of mother-to-child transmission) on its Essential Drugs List.[148]
There is much debate about the comparative relevance of patents and other factors in determining access to medicines. We consider it important that all these factors are addressed. But we also do not consider that there is a real trade-off between improving IP arrangements to pursue the objectives of public health and addressing the issues of policy, infrastructure and resources for the same objectives. Both need to be pursued, and pursuing one has no bearing on one’s ability to pursue the other. One of the participants at our conference said:
“…I would like to discourage the Commission from arriving at the conclusion in this debate {that it is all} about infrastructure and resources. If that is the conclusion, I think you will have what the title says: "People are Poor". So don't make recommendations that people are poor because we know that. We are trying to solve their problems, not to tell them that they are poor.”[149]
Countries need to adopt a range of policies to improve
access to medicines. Additional
resources to improve services, delivery mechanisms and infrastructure are
critical. Other macroeconomic policies
need to be in harmony with health policy objectives. But so also does the IP regime. Countries need to ensure that
their IP protection regimes do not run counter to their public health policies
and that they are consistent with and supportive of such policies.
POLICY IMPLICATIONS
The context of our discussion of the policy implications is the Doha Declaration agreed at the WTO Ministerial Meeting in Doha in November 2001 (see Box 2.1). Ministers clarified that TRIPS should not prevent countries from taking measures to protect public health. They confirmed that, within the terms of the agreement, compulsory licences could be granted on grounds determined by member countries. Moreover, domestic demand could be supplied by parallel imports (governed in legal terms by what is known as the “exhaustion of rights” doctrine).[150] They recognised that a special problem existed for countries with insufficient manufacturing capacity in making use of compulsory licensing, and instructed the TRIPS Council to find a solution by the end of this year. Members also agreed to exempt least developed countries from implementing, applying or enforcing pharmaceutical product and test data protection[151] until 2016. The TRIPS Council confirmed this decision on 27 June 2002. The Council at the same time approved a waiver that would exempt LDCs from having to provide exclusive marketing rights for any new drugs in the period when they do not provide patent protection. The latter waiver, now approved by the General Council of WTO, has to be reviewed annually by the Ministerial Conference of WTO (or the General Council between Ministerial meetings) until it terminates.
The premise of our recommendations is that for most developing countries any benefits in terms of the development of new treatments for diseases that afflict them will be, at best, long term, while the costs of implementing a patent system are both real and immediate. Thus we concentrate on measures within the IP system that will reduce to a minimum the prices of drugs, while maintaining their availability. As noted above, we have not found evidence to suggest such measures will diminish the incentives for research on diseases specific to developing countries, because it is the lack of demand rather than the IP system which is the determining factor. But we recognise that, because we are entering uncharted waters, continuing research will be necessary to establish how much TRIPS implementation in practice affects both research incentives and access, particularly in the longer term.
Box 2.1 Doha WTO Ministerial Declaration on TRIPS and Public Health
Adopted on 14 November 2001
1. We
recognize the gravity of the public health problems afflicting many developing
and least-developed countries, especially those resulting from HIV/AIDS, TB,
malaria and other epidemics.
2. We stress
the need for the WTO Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual
Property Rights (TRIPS Agreement) to be part of the wider national and
international action to address these problems.
3. We
recognize that intellectual property protection is important for the
development of new medicines. We also
recognize the concerns about its effects on prices.
4. We
agree that the TRIPS Agreement does not and should not prevent Members from
taking measures to protect public health.
Accordingly, while reiterating our commitment to the TRIPS Agreement, we
affirm that the Agreement can and should be interpreted and implemented in a
manner supportive of WTO Members' right to protect public health and, in
particular, to promote access to medicines for all.
In this connection, we reaffirm the right of WTO
Members to use, to the full, the provisions in the TRIPS Agreement, which
provide flexibility for this purpose.
5. Accordingly
and in the light of paragraph 4 above, while maintaining our commitments in the
TRIPS Agreement, we recognize that these flexibilities include:
a) In applying the customary rules of interpretation
of public international law, each provision of the TRIPS Agreement shall be
read in the light of the object and purpose of the Agreement as expressed, in
particular, in its objectives and principles.
b) Each Member has the right to grant compulsory
licences and the freedom to determine the grounds upon which such licences are
granted.
c) Each Member has the right to determine what
constitutes a national emergency or other circumstances of extreme urgency, it
being understood that public health crises, including those relating to
HIV/AIDS, TB, malaria and other epidemics, can represent a national emergency
or other circumstances of extreme urgency.
d) The effect of the provisions in the TRIPS Agreement
that are relevant to the exhaustion of intellectual property rights is to leave
each Member free to establish its own regime for such exhaustion without
challenge, subject to the MFN and national treatment provisions of Articles 3
& 4.
6. We
recognize that WTO Members with insufficient or no manufacturing capacities in
the pharmaceutical sector could face difficulties in making effective use of
compulsory licensing under the TRIPS Agreement. We instruct the Council for TRIPS to find an expeditious solution
to this problem and to report to the General Council before the end of 2002.
7. We
reaffirm the commitment of developed-country Members to provide incentives to
their enterprises and institutions to promote and encourage technology transfer
to least-developed country Members pursuant to Article 66.2. We also agree that the least-developed
country Members will not be obliged, with respect to pharmaceutical products,
to implement or apply Sections 5 and 7 of Part II of the TRIPS Agreement or to
enforce rights provided for under these Sections until 1 January 2016, without
prejudice to the right of least-developed country Members to seek other
extensions of the transition periods as provided for in Article 66.1 of the
TRIPS Agreement. We instruct the
Council for TRIPS to take the necessary action to give effect to this pursuant
to Article 66.1 of the TRIPS Agreement.
Differential
Pricing
As we have noted, differential pricing in principle should be an economically rational way for global companies to maximise their profits on products that are sold in both low and high income markets.[152] It should also be a way of ensuring that poorer people obtain less expensive products.
There are several initiatives aimed at facilitating a global system of differential pricing. As noted above, there are many other factors unrelated to IPRs that affect the prices and availability of medicines. In establishing a differential pricing system, which would allow low prices in developing countries to coexist with higher prices in developed countries, there are two important factors:
· Markets with different price levels must be segmented so that low priced medicines cannot enter higher priced markets. This means controlling exports and imports of relevant products.
· Pricing decisions in higher priced markets, where these are set or influenced by government policy, must not be made by reference to prices in the low priced markets.
The second factor does not involve IP considerations, but represents a political problem in many developed countries because of the existing variation in prices of pharmaceuticals, even between developed countries, and the pressure on the budgets of patients, insurance schemes and the state to meet ever rising bills for patented drugs.
But the tools of the IP system, including parallel imports and compulsory licensing, are likely to play an essential part in underpinning differential pricing and market segmentation. In order to ensure an effective operation of a differential pricing system, national laws in developing countries should retain the right for the government to admit parallel imports and to issue compulsory licences.
We are also
aware of recent price reductions and of the number of special schemes operated
by some companies, sometimes in cooperation with international agencies, to
provide heavily discounted or free drugs and, in conjunction with local
government and NGOs, supportive infrastructure to ensure delivery to the
patient. These offers generally apply
only to purchasers who are governments, NGOs, aid organisations or private
sector employers, not commercial suppliers of medicines. These are all welcome contributions to
improving access to medicines in developing countries.[153] But there is also the need to seek more
broad-based solutions, which are also sustainable, to the serious public health
problems that are being addressed. That
is why continued efforts are required to make differential pricing
effective.
In principle, it is undesirable for there to be restrictions upon the free movement of products once placed on the market by a manufacturer. But in practice and strictly for the purpose of ensuring that lower priced products can be supplied to and only to those who need the lower prices, it may be necessary to derogate from that general principle. Therefore an important component in establishing a system of differential pricing is that markets need to be segmented to prevent low priced products undermining high priced markets. For that purpose, it is essential that developed countries put in place effective mechanisms that prevent parallel importing of medicines. This is already broadly the case for the US and the EU, but appears not to be so for Japan.[154]
Developed
countries should maintain and strengthen their legislative regimes to prevent
imports of low priced pharmaceutical products originating from developing
countries.
However, to secure the segmentation of
markets, it would also be desirable for developing countries to act to prevent
exports to developed countries of drugs that are part of a donation or
differential pricing scheme. It is
especially important to avoid product diversion from those patients for whom
the medicine is intended. But,
recognising limitations in their capacity for enforcement, the primary burden
of segmentation between developed and developing countries will realistically
need to rest with developed countries.
Developing countries should not eliminate potential sources of low cost imports, from other developing or developed countries. In order to be an effective pro-competitive measure in a scenario of full compliance with TRIPS, parallel imports should be allowed whenever the patentee’s rights have been exhausted in the foreign country. Since TRIPS allows countries to design their own exhaustion of rights regimes (a point restated at Doha), developing countries should aim to facilitate parallel imports in their legislation.
Compulsory Licensing
As noted above, the result of implementing TRIPS will be to curtail the supply of generic copies of patented products. This will remove an important element in restraining and reducing the prices of patented products in developing countries. Providing effective legislation and procedures for compulsory licensing may have an important role to play in maintaining a pro-competitive IPR policy in the new environment. We do not regard compulsory licensing as a panacea, but rather as an essential insurance policy to prevent abuses of the IP system.
Although TRIPS allows compulsory licensing (as clarified in the Doha Declaration), subject to certain procedures and conditions, developing countries have yet to use it. Ironically, it is the developed countries that have been the most active users of compulsory licensing (not only in the pharmaceutical field) for a number of purposes, including importantly in anti-trust cases in the US. Canada used compulsory licensing extensively in the pharmaceutical field from 1969 until the late 1980s. This resulted in prices of licensed drugs being 47% lower than in the US in 1982.[155] The UK also used compulsory licensing until the 1970’s, including for important drugs such as Librium and Valium. More recently in 2001, the US Secretary for Health and Human Services (HHS), publicly envisaged the possibility of procuring generic equivalents prior to his negotiations with Bayer (the patentee) on the purchase of the drug Cipro to deal with the consequences of anthrax attacks although, in the end, agreement was reached with Bayer.[156]
Developing countries have not used the system for a number of reasons. First, it requires an administrative and legal infrastructure that is absent in many developing countries. Secondly, developing countries have feared that sanctions might be threatened, bilaterally or multilaterally. Thirdly, compulsory licensing has to be “predominantly for the domestic market”. Fourthly, the word compulsory refers to the legitimate limitation of patent owner rights by a government. The actual producer of the licensed drug manufactures voluntarily and for profit (at least in the case of a private sector licensee). Thus the licensee must have the know-how to reverse engineer and manufacture the drug without the cooperation of the patent owner, and must also foresee a sufficiently large market to justify the costs of investment and manufacture and adequate remuneration to the patentee. If these conditions are not fulfilled, the threat of a compulsory licence will not be credible.
The threat of compulsory licensing has been successfully used by Brazil in the pursuit of its National STD/AIDS Programme (see Box 2.2). As a result of its research capability, and the development of public sector manufacturing capacity, Brazil has been able to use the threat of compulsory licensing in negotiations with pharmaceutical companies. This includes an ability to use estimates of its own production costs under compulsory licensing when negotiating prices with patentees. But there are relatively few developing countries which are in the same position as Brazil, so the threat will lack credibility in most developing countries unless they are able to rely on imports from countries with the requisite capacity.
Box 2.2 The Brazilian National STD/AIDS Programme
(NSAP)
The primary mission of the Brazilian National STD/AIDS
Programme (NSAP) is to make HIV/AIDS medications available free of charge to
all citizens who need them though the national public health care system. NSAP was initiated in the early 1990s and
the treatment of HIV/AIDS patients was made a legal obligation in 1996. With
the assistance of HIV/AIDS NGOs, there has been a major reorganisation of the
national public health services network for drug distribution, AIDS testing and
care. There are now hundreds of Drugs Dispensing Units across the country.
NSAP now supplies anti-retroviral drugs to currently
nearly 105,000 of Brazil’s estimated 600000 HIV/AIDS patients. It has now
reduced the number of cases of HIV and mortality among AIDS victims to half
what was predicted in the early 1990s. Hospital admissions have decreased by 80
percent since 1996. So, although the
NSAP is expensive (the total annual cost is about US$500m out of a total health
budget of US$10bn), the costs avoided due to reduced illness, hospitalisation
and other impacts of HIV/AIDS are beginning to balance the budget. The Brazilian Ministry of Health estimates
that in 2001, the final cost of NSAP, incorporating reduced morbidity
expenditure, was negative (a net saving of US$50m).[157]
Of the total cost of the programme, $300 million is
spent on AIDS drugs. The cost of
acquiring the antiretroviral drugs has reduced recently, as the Ministry of
Health/NSAP develops local production in the public sector - establishing
national laboratories, and tools to negotiate with multinational companies,
including the threat of compulsory licensing.
Far-Manguinhos (part of the Oswaldo Cruz Foundation - FIOCRUZ) is the
main government drug producer, developing the technology that provides the
country with low-cost anti-retroviral drugs. The institute already produces
seven of the 15 medicines used in the antiretroviral cocktail offered in
Brazil. None of these drugs are
patented in Brazil. The prices of these
drugs, when developed for local production, fell by an average of 72.5% between
1996 and 2000. In 1999, 47% of
antiretrovirals were produced in Brazil but accounted for only 19% of total
expenditures. Thus 81% of expenditure
was on ARVs purchased from multi-national companies.
Because Far-Manguinhos has the technical capacity to
reverse engineer patented drugs, and can estimate realistic production costs,
the Health Ministry is in a strong bargaining position for negotiating price
reductions with foreign producers, backed up by the credible threat of
compulsory licensing. In 2001 the
Health Minister used this approach with Roche and Merck for their drugs
Nelfinavir and Efavirenz, eventually negotiating price reductions of 40 to
70%.
While Brazil’s programme has been widely acclaimed as
a possible model for other countries, it needs to be noted that the cost of the
programme amounts to nearly $5000 per annum per treated person, or $800 for
each HIV infected person, or $3 for every person in Brazil. Thus Brazil has
prioritised the treatment of HIV/AIDS. This is affordable for Brazil because it
is a relatively affluent developing country, and because in proportionate terms
it has a low rate of HIV infection. Moreover,
its technical know-how allows the Ministry of Health to negotiate price
reductions effectively. As noted above,
it may be an investment that pays for itself in reduced mortality and
morbidity. But the initial investment
in this type of programme may not be affordable in poorer countries with much
higher rates of HIV infection, without external assistance. For such nations, their weak technological
capacity will also be a constraint in the absence of effective means of
compulsorily licensing as proposed in Doha.
National Arrangements for Compulsory Licensing
An important barrier to compulsory licensing in developing countries is the absence of straightforward legislative and administrative procedures to put it into effect. Because legal systems in most developing countries are overburdened, it would be most appropriate to legislate for a quasi-judicial and independent administrative system for implementation of compulsory licensing. The essential elements would include:
· straightforward, transparent and fast procedures
· procedures for appeals that do not suspend the execution of the licence
· legislation that fully exploits the flexibilities in TRIPS for determining the grounds for compulsory licensing, as well as for non-commercial use by government, including production for export (see below)
· clear, easy to apply, and transparent guidelines for setting royalty rates (which may vary).
There is much to be learnt from the experience of developed countries, particularly Canada, which seems to have had the most comprehensive programme. Canada set a more or less universal royalty rate of 4%, for which an early precedent was set in an important test case. US practice has varied considerably from very low rates to quite high, depending on Court judgements. Developing countries will need to develop rules and procedures adapted to their own circumstances for setting royalty rates, but the implication of other countries’ experience is that royalty rates need not be very high.
Developing countries also need to consider adopting in this context strong provisions on government and non-commercial use. This is different from compulsory licensing but has a similar effect in the public health sector. Again, many developed (and developing) countries have such provisions in their laws. In Commonwealth countries these derive from the British 1883 Act, which has been retained in current law.[158] These powers are quite sweeping and do not specify closely particular circumstances in which they can be used. For instance, in New Zealand:
“…any Government Department …may make, use, exercise
and vend any patented invention for the services of the Crown and anything done
by virtue of this subsection shall not amount to an infringement of the patent
concerned.”[159]
Developing countries should establish workable laws and procedures to give effect to compulsory licensing, and provide appropriate provisions for government use.
Paragraph six of the Doha Declaration directs the TRIPS Council to develop an expeditious solution to the problem faced by certain countries not having sufficient manufacturing capacity in the pharmaceutical sector. It defines the problem as the inability of these countries to use compulsory licensing to obtain needed pharmaceuticals from a producer located in their territory. A compulsory licence ordinarily could be used for this purpose - the country could authorise through a compulsory licence a domestic producer to produce the product within its territory, or an importer to procure from elsewhere. The countries identified as having this problem, however, cannot turn to a domestic producer for products under this approach, and would need to rely on a producer from another country.
We agree that it is important to get the interpretation or amendment of TRIPS right, bearing in mind the longer term scenario when patent protection will apply to countries that can currently produce and export generic copies of patented drugs. The ultimate need is to create a pro-competitive solution for the market in patented drugs in developing countries after TRIPS is fully in force which allows expeditious procurement of drugs in a sustainable manner at the lowest possible cost. This applies whether we are considering the direct procurement of patented drugs where there are a range of therapeutic substitutes, or about procurement under compulsory licensing.
Compulsory licensing needs to be viewed as a means to an end. The end in this case is to help achieve the lowest possible cost of medicines in developing countries in order to facilitate access. The only point of compulsory licensing in this context is if it will help to achieve this. As noted above, aside from the legal and administrative aspects, compulsory licensing will only be effective if the compulsory licensee sees the possibility of a reasonable return from his investment while also supplying at a significantly lower price than the patentee (or his licensee).
While there are
now several countries, particularly those with significant domestic markets,
with the capacity to produce copies of drugs cheaply, this will become more
difficult after 2005. There will be no
incentive, as now, for manufacturers in these countries to reverse engineer
newly patented drugs and take the other steps necessary for manufacture and
sale (including obtaining regulatory approval), because the domestic market
would be closed. Thus the ready supply
of generic substitutes for patented drugs now available will gradually
disappear. Potential compulsory
licensees would therefore have to charge a price closer to full economic cost
(including start-up and manufacturing costs) as compared to the possibility of
providing off-the-shelf generics at prices where start-up costs have already
been amortised to some extent on the domestic market. Moreover, if the necessary investment is only triggered by the
availability of a compulsory licence, there will inevitably be long delays
before the drug actually reaches the intended patients.[160] In addition, there is some evidence that
reverse engineering of new medicines is intrinsically more difficult in
biopharmaceuticals than in traditional process chemistry.
This suggests that, without special arrangements, the possibility of compulsory licensing being a vehicle for price reductions will be more limited than at present, even in the few technologically advanced developing countries. For most countries, the only feasible supplier may be the patentee (or his licensee).
We therefore see the problem identified at Doha as being as much economic as legal. A quasi-legal solution as may be identified in the TRIPS Council is necessary, but is by no means sufficient to solve the problem we have outlined. In particular the quasi-legal solution is less likely to be effective the more compulsory licensing is hedged around with restrictions. Such restrictions reduce the likelihood that such licensing can be an effective bargaining tool for developing countries negotiating prices with patentees – it can be effective only if the compulsory licensing alternative is a viable economic proposition.
In this section we consider and comment on the various proposals put forward by different countries and groups of countries to address the WTO resolution of the problem identified in paragraph 6 of the Doha Declaration. This revolves around the substance of Articles 28 (Rights Conferred), Article 30 (Exceptions to Rights Conferred) and Article 31(f) of TRIPS, where Article 31 deals with “Other Use Without Authorisation of the Right Holder”. Article 31(f) provides that a compulsory licence must be “predominantly for the supply of the domestic market of the Member authorising such use.”
Countries with no or insufficient manufacturing capacity cannot therefore issue a compulsory licence to a domestic manufacturer, or to one overseas because patents are territorial. At present they could issue a compulsory licence to an importer, who could source the supply from a generic manufacturer in a country where the product is not patented. After 2005, this option will not be possible for drugs that are patented in the supplier country.
The practical effect of this provision is to render the compulsory licensing provisions practically worthless for the very countries which are likely to need it most – namely the poorest. With limited domestic manufacturing capacity, there is no one to invoke those provisions in those countries. This is plainly unsatisfactory and the Doha Declaration rightly recognised that a swift solution should be found to this problem.
There are a number of interpretative problems raised by the Doha Declaration, a few of which we note in passing. The Declaration notes that countries are free to determine the grounds on which compulsory licences are granted (paragraph 5b), and the right to determine what constitutes a “national emergency or other circumstances of extreme urgency” (paragraph 5c). The latter provision reflects the shortcut in procedures allowed in these circumstances in Article 31(b) of TRIPS. Thus paragraph six refers to procedures for compulsory licensing in the pharmaceutical sector needed to address “public health problems…especially those resulting from HIV/AIDS, tuberculosis, malaria and other epidemics” (paragraph 1).[161] It does not, as sometimes assumed, refer only to compulsory licensing in situations of emergency or urgency. Nor is it limited to a particular type of disease.
It also needs to be clarified which countries have no or insufficient manufacturing capacity. Again we think this requires an economic interpretation. If production of a needed medicine is technically possible but extremely costly, there is no point in issuing a domestic compulsory licence. If the objective is affordable access to medicines of appropriate quality and quantity, then the solution should allow production in the most economically viable manner, whether domestically or overseas. Developing countries generally favour an interpretation of “manufacturing capacity”, that takes account of economic criteria (for example, whether the capacity is such that economic production is possible in the envisaged circumstances), and place emphasis on a country’s ability to decide the criteria on a product by product basis. Developed countries, with one exception, suggest that criteria for defining this should be drawn up, without defining what these might be.[162]
Since the Declaration also allows LDCs not to apply pharmaceutical patents until 2016, countries that take advantage of this provision will not be able to issue compulsory licences, nor will any country where a patent has not been taken out. At present, such countries may be able to import cheaper supplies from other countries without patents on the relevant products, but again this situation will change after 2005. Thus paragraph six, while referring specifically to compulsory licensing, is clearly intended to address this wider context of action to address the affordability and accessibility of medicines, particularly in developing and least developed countries.
The Declaration does not specify which countries may act as suppliers to the countries in question. In order to maximise competition, and achieve the lowest prices possible, applying no restriction on which WTO members may act as suppliers would seem to be the logical market-based solution. For the same reasons, countries seeking a licence should logically seek out the most competitive compulsory licensee, wherever they might be located. Developing countries favour having the ability to import from suppliers in any country. One developed country favours the possibility of import from developed countries, but the EU has no fixed views and the US favours supply from developing countries only, as does the research-based pharmaceutical industry.
Five main solutions have been proposed to the problem mentioned in paragraph 6 of the Declaration which we examine in turn.
The Amendment of Article 31 of TRIPS. Article 31(f) could be deleted. However this may be regarded as altering the sense of the Agreement for compulsory licensing other than in relation to public health problems. The alternative is an amendment which would make a clearly demarcated exception to the restriction imposed by Article 31(f) covering compulsory licensing needed to address public health problems envisaged in the Declaration. Such an amendment to TRIPS would be very time-consuming and require ratification by national governments. An interim or provisional solution, such as a declaration of intent, and temporary waiver or moratorium on dispute settlement, could be provided to cover the period until any amendment is ratified. But many countries, both developed and developing may be reluctant to re-open TRIPS at all, because of the risk of other aspects of the agreement being opened up for renegotiation at the same time. Assuming a solution was found, it would then be necessary for a potential exporting country to delete the “predominantly” clause from its own legislation and to make sure that the grounds for compulsory licensing accorded with those envisaged in the Declaration. In the final stage compulsory licences would need to be invoked and paid for in both the importing and exporting countries, if there is a patent in both. The exporting country would need to be prepared, in any case, to issue a compulsory licence for the benefit of the importing country.
Developing countries have suggested a number of options for resolving the problem including the revision of Article 31 or deletion of Article 31(f), so as to ensure Article 31(f) would not apply to any laws, measures and administrative regulations including compulsory licences, adopted to protect public health and in particular to ensure affordable access to pharmaceutical products. Other developing countries note that under Article 31(f) there would be a need to issue compulsory licences in both the importing and exporting country which would be administratively burdensome. The EU favours the specific amendment to Article 31(f) described above. The US does not favour an amendment to 31(f), but a moratorium on dispute settlement proceedings to achieve the same effect.
Interpretation of Article 30. Article 30 provides for limited exemptions to patent rights that do not conflict with the normal exploitation of the patent. Under this proposed solution no amendment is required to TRIPS, nor a compulsory licence in the exporting country. One claimed advantage is that it would allow exports to countries where no patents exist on the relevant medicine. All that would seem to be required is an “authoritative interpretation” under Article IX of the WTO agreement, adopted by three quarters of WTO Members. This would clarify that an exception under patent rights to allow export in the circumstances envisaged in the Declaration is legitimate. National legislation in the exporting country would then need to be amended to ensure that the envisaged exception is incorporated. One issue with this proposed solution is whether the “Doha exception” would be compatible with the conditions of Article 30. An interpretation of this Article in a recent Disputes Settlement Panel[163] suggested that the “limited exceptions” should be interpreted narrowly. This was in the context of justifying Canada’s provision of an exception for early working by potential competitors for the purposes of obtaining regulatory approval. There is a case to be made that an exception, as suggested here, is “limited” to particular circumstances as defined in the Declaration. It could also be said that it does not “unreasonably conflict” with the normal exploitation of the patent, being for export at low prices, provided the “legitimate interests” of the patentee are safeguarded (for example, preventing diversion to other markets). Moreover, the legitimate interests of third parties (people suffering from diseases in developing countries) would need to be weighed appropriately against those of the patentee. For the most part the very different circumstances applying here, as contrasted to those in the Canada case, means this WTO case law is of limited relevance.
Some developing countries particularly favour the Article 30 solution, noting that it solves the problem of double remuneration under Article 31, and removes the need for a compulsory licence in the exporting country. In terms of administrative procedures they feel it is the least burdensome option. It should also be noted that activist NGOs think the Article 30 option is preferable to other options.
Moratorium or Waiver. An alternative is the proposal for a moratorium or waiver for exports in the “Doha circumstances”. Advocates argue that a waiver is the most expeditious solution noting that it could provide legal security and still avoid the need for either amendment or authoritative interpretation of the TRIPS agreement. The conditions for a waiver could be set out in advance to define the circumstances in which they would apply. Obviously there would be a need to set these out very clearly and unambiguously to the satisfaction of all WTO members. This has not yet been attempted and clarity may inevitably be compromised in negotiations on the criteria.
The WTO Ministerial Council would have to agree the criteria under which Members may be exempted from complying with the provisions of the TRIPS Agreement. Both in the case of a moratorium and a waiver, however, interested parties may only invoke protection under the Agreement if national legislation has been changed to implement the exemption to the 31(f) requirement.[164] If national legislation is not changed, a patentee may still make a case in national courts in spite of the fact that a WTO waiver or moratorium applies. It also needs to be remembered that a waiver requires regular review by the Ministerial Conference/General Council if granted for a period of more than one year.
The EU have
suggested that a waiver (or moratorium) might be necessary while the amendment
they propose to 31(f) is agreed. Some
developing countries have suggested that that a waiver (or moratorium) would
not amount to a sustainable and legally predictable solution. By contrast the US has suggested that a
waiver or moratorium is more likely to achieve an expeditious, workable,
transparent, sustainable and legally certain solution. We also understand that the pharmaceutical
industry supports a proposal on these lines.
Non-Justiciability. The proposal for a non-justiciability option would achieve much of the Article 30 approach by a different means. It would operate in a similar manner to the position of TRIPS on the exhaustion of rights (paragraph six of TRIPS). By authoritative interpretation or amendment of the Agreement, it would be decided that settlement disputes under TRIPS would not be used to in relation to exports undertaken as envisaged in the Declaration. However, it is unclear exactly how this proposal would be implemented.
Export by a Nation with a Compulsory Licence. A final option, which is not in the hands of the WTO, is that countries which have the capacity to reverse engineer and manufacture, and large local markets for the required medicines, may issue compulsory licences in accordance with their own legislation. In that case, a proportion of the supplies manufactured could be offered for export to countries in need (on the basis of a compulsory licence for import if necessary) in a manner that did not breach Article 31(f). A compulsory licence can also be granted to remedy anti-competitive practices (Article 31(k)), and in this case the restriction on exports would not apply. But this option depends on the supplying country having legitimate grounds for issuing a compulsory licence in the first place, on its having a large enough market that exports constitute less than half of total production, and on its willingness to export.
The
choice between these options will be worked out politically, but we strongly
emphasise our concern that whatever the legal solution adopted by the WTO is,
it should proceed upon the following principles. First, it should be quickly and easily implementable with a view
to a long term solution. Second, the
solution should ensure that the needs of poor people in developing countries
without manufacturing capacity are given priority. Third, it should seek to ensure that conditions are established
to provide potential suppliers the necessary incentive to export medicines that
are needed
Economic Aspects
Whatever means are utilised to achieve the objectives at Doha, developed countries will require safeguards to prevent leakage of product from the intended recipient to other markets, and to ensure that production is only for export to the affected country, not for domestic sale. They may also require actions through WTO to ensure all Members are fully informed of the nature of the transaction in a transparent manner. Whatever safeguards are finally agreed upon, the crucial issue is that the economics of supply to one particular country with a limited market may be insufficient to attract potential generic suppliers. Moreover, if prices offered under compulsory licensing are to be as low as possible, then there should be competition between more than one supplier at the point of ordering, if not for the actual supply. To allow therefore for economies of scale, and a degree of competition, it is important that small markets are grouped together as much as is possible.
An obvious solution is for groups of countries with the similar needs for essential drugs to group together. International institutions, such as WHO or the Global Fund to Fight AIDS, Tuberculosis and Malaria (GFATM) may also have an essential role to play in facilitating and financing group purchases of medicines from both brand and generic manufacturers.
A way needs to be found to reconcile the nature of the solution adopted with the objective of providing medicines of the appropriate quality at the lowest possible cost. If that cannot be achieved, the legal solution will have little practical reality. Nor will the option of compulsory licensing be effective as a negotiating tool.
The main way that developing countries can use IPRs to address public health issues is to ensure that their legislation provides for appropriate standards and practices. What is appropriate will vary according to country circumstances and level of development. For instance, countries with well developed R&D capability, or with particular strengths in, say, biotechnology, may want to have “stronger” protection than countries that are almost entirely users of other countries’ technology.
Developing countries should not feel compelled, or indeed be compelled, to adopt developed country standards for IPR regimes. They might be overwhelmed if they did so. The number of new chemical entities approved for use by the US Food and Drug Administration (FDA) declined to 27 in 2000, compared to about 60 in 1985.[165] But the number of patents granted in the main patent class for new drug compositions (424) was 6730 in 2000.[166] The great majority of patents are granted not for new therapeutic compounds, but relate to variations in production processes, new formulations or crystalline forms, new combinations of known products, and new uses of known drugs. In the period 1989-2000, 153 of the 1035 new drug approvals by the FDA were reported to be for drugs that contained new active ingredients and offered significant clinical improvement. A further 472 drugs were classified as being modestly innovative.[167]
The underlying principle should be to aim for strict
standards of patentability and narrow scope of allowed claims, with the
objective of:
·
limiting the scope of subject matter that can be patented
·
applying standards such that only patents which meet strict
requirements for patentability are granted and that the breadth of each patent
is commensurate with the inventive contribution and the disclosure made
·
facilitating competition by restricting the ability of the patentees
to prohibit others from building on or
designing around patented inventions
·
providing extensive safeguards to ensure that patent rights are not
exploited inappropriately.
All this would help to ensure that patenting rules as far as possible limit the scope for patenting that serves more to protect markets, and exclude competition, than promote local R&D. Moreover loose patenting standards and practices, as noted above, can actually inhibit innovation by impeding research by others. Because, under TRIPS, it is not possible to discriminate between different fields of technology, we deal with the application of these principles in more detail in Chapter 6.
However,
specific to pharmaceuticals, most developing countries should as a minimum take
up the possibility allowed by TRIPS[168]
of excluding diagnostic, therapeutic and surgical methods for treatments of
humans or animals from patentability, as well as new uses of known products
(which, in essence, are equivalent to therapeutic methods). Since most developing countries are not in a
position to develop such methods, they will have nothing to gain by not
exploiting this flexibility. Of course,
the few developing countries with research capabilities in these areas may wish
to have such protection, but we should note that most developed countries also
exclude these areas from patentability.
We would also suggest that developing countries think very carefully
about diluting this exception by relaxing the concept of novelty and allowing
patent claims for essentially first or subsequent medical uses of known
chemical compounds as has been done in a number of developed and developing
countries.[169] Again, developed countries may consider that
the incentive for research justifies allowing such claims, but for most
developing countries with limited research capabilities we consider that the
costs are likely to outweigh the benefits.
Most developing countries, particularly those without
research capabilities, should strictly exclude diagnostic, therapeutic and
surgical methods from patentability, including new uses of known products.
We also deal here with two issues which particularly affect the pharmaceutical sector, and the production of generic drugs.
Bolar Exception
In the US,
the Drug Price Competition and Patent Term Restoration Act of 1984 overturned a
landmark court decision (Roche versus Bolar, 1984) by introducing, inter alia,
what is now known as the “Bolar Exception” (or “early working exception”). This makes it legal for a generic producer
to import, manufacture and test a patented product prior to the expiry of the patent
in order that it may fulfil the regulatory requirements imposed by particular
countries as necessary for marketing as a generic. The WTO legality of this exception was confirmed in 2000 by the
dispute settlement case brought by the EU against Canada.[170] For developing countries this is very
important, particularly if they are actual or potential producers of generics,
in order to ensure that lower priced generics can reach the market as soon as a
patent expires. Even if they are not
likely to be potential producers in the foreseeable future, it would be prudent
to include the exception in their legislation.
For instance, a foreign company may need to conduct trials for the
purpose of gaining regulatory approval.
Of 63 developing countries whose legislation we examined only eight
specifically included a Bolar exception, although others may also allow “early
working” under general exceptions to exclusive rights (covered by equivalent
wording to Article 30 in TRIPS).[171]
Developing countries should include an appropriate exception for “early working” to patent rights in their legislation, which will accelerate the introduction of generic substitutes on patent expiry.
Marketing Approval
Another
important step in marketing a generic drug is the need to meet regulatory
requirements for that purpose. TRIPS
provides in Article 39.3 an obligation on countries to protect against unfair
commercial use of confidential data (for example, trials data) on new chemical
entities submitted by companies to obtain approval for marketing new drugs from
the regulatory agency (such as the FDA in the US).
The rationale
for this is the “considerable effort” invested in the compilation of this
data. Pharmaceutical companies
understandably argue that it is unfair if the product of possibly millions of
dollars of clinical trials and other investigations is made available to
competitors who thereby avoid the need for comparable expenditure in order to
obtain marketing approval. Against
this it is argued, from the public health point of view, that such data should
be in the public domain because they contain important medical information not
available elsewhere and that excessive secrecy has undesirable effects (for
example, the data might be usefully reanalysed to understand side-effects only
detected after marketing). Moreover,
from a societal point of view, it makes no sense for a potential generic
competitor to repeat very expensive tests if the biopharmaceutical equivalence
of their version of the drug can be reliably demonstrated. Data exclusivity can be a barrier to generic
entry irrespective of whether the drug was patented, or the patent period has
expired.
TRIPS does
not require the imposition of data exclusivity, as such, on these test data,
only protection against unfair commercial use.
The EU, however, has rules that confer exclusivity on such data for a
period of six to ten years, and is considering moving to ten years. This means, inter alia, that the health
authorities cannot rely on such data to approve other applications without the
originators’ consent. In the US,
similar protection is applicable for five years.
In the light
of the above, we take the view that developing countries should protect test
data against unfair commercial use in order to protect the legitimate interests
of the originators of data and their “considerable effort”. But TRIPS allows considerable freedom in how
this may be done.
Countries may allow health authorities
to approve equivalent generic substitutes by “relying on” the original
data. Developing countries should
implement data protection legislation that facilitates the entry of generic
competitors, whilst providing appropriate protection for confidential data,
which may be done in a variety of TRIPS-compatible ways. Developing countries need not enact
legislation the effect of which is to create exclusive rights where no patent
protection exists or to extend the effective period of the patent monopoly
beyond its proper term.
Doha Extension for Least Developed Countries
The Doha Declaration (paragraph seven) instructed the TRIPS Council to allow least developed countries to defer introduction of patent protection for pharmaceutical products and protection of confidential test data until at least 2016. We applaud the intention behind this paragraph, but it also creates and highlights a number of anomalies.
At least 70% of the population in LDCs are in countries that provide pharmaceutical patent protection, and 27 of the 30 LDCs in Africa also provide it. These countries would need to amend their legislation to remove protection on pharmaceuticals to take advantage of this extension. It may well be in their interest to do so in view of the length of the extension granted. We presume, however, that amendments to legislation may not be retrospective and thus current patents would remain valid.
Further, certain countries will be constrained in amending their laws by bilateral or multilateral agreements. For instance the 12 LDC members of OAPI (three are not least developed) would need to agree on a revision to the Bangui Treaty which governs OAPI. Similarly, others may be bound by bilateral agreements which do not allow for this course of action.
For countries that have not yet implemented IP protection, we question whether it makes sense to implement the whole IP protection regime in 2006, except for pharmaceutical protection. Since pharmaceuticals account for a significant proportion of all patent applications (for example, 50 % of patents issued by ARIPO in 1994-1999 were related to pharmaceutical products),[172] it is even harder to justify the financial and human resources necessary for implementing an IP regime in these countries, only for non-pharmaceutical sectors. Article 66.1 of TRIPS provides that the TRIPS Council may grant extensions to the transition period for LDCs taking account of their “special needs and requirements…their economic, financial and administrative constraints, and their need for flexibility to create a viable technological base”. It is not therefore very logical to grant an extension for one sector on the grounds of public health to a specific future date, when the criteria under TRIPS for granting extensions are far more broadly based.
Those LDCs which already provide pharmaceutical protection should consider carefully how to amend their legislation to take advantage of the Doha Declaration. Consistent with our analysis elsewhere, the TRIPS Council should review the transitional arrangements for LDCs, including those applying to join the WTO, in all fields of technology.
Background
The importance of the agricultural sector in developing countries as a source of food, incomes, employment and often foreign exchange cannot be overstated. As much as good health, a productive and sustainable agricultural sector is critical to achieving economic growth and poverty reduction. About three quarters of the world’s poor people live and work in rural areas.[173] Apart from its direct role in sustaining incomes and employment, the role of agriculture, and in particular technological change in agriculture, in stimulating overall economic growth has been much discussed by economists and policymakers. Raising productivity in agriculture can directly increase the incomes and employment levels of the majority of poor people dependent on agriculture. It can also help to reduce food prices (relatively or absolutely) for poor people in both rural and urban sectors.
Historically agriculture has been seen, sometimes controversially, as a source of food, labour and finance to supply a growing urban and industrial sector on which sustained growth in incomes will depend. Achieving this transition usually depends on achieving productivity increases if food prices are not to rise, and stifle both industrial growth and poverty reduction. In developed countries changes in technology and institutions in the agricultural sector are regarded as having been instrumental in the industrial revolution.
In developing countries, technical progress traditionally occurred through a process of on-farm experimentation, selection and adaptation of traditional landraces[174] of crops. Subsequently this was supplemented by purposive breeding of new varieties of crops, mainly through crossing varieties with desirable characteristics. This process of research was largely conducted in the public sector by national research institutes, supported by a network of international research institutes, for the last thirty years under the umbrella of the Consultative Group on International Agricultural Research (CGIAR). It was this network which led to the Green Revolution of the 1960s, based initially on high yielding semi-dwarf varieties of rice and wheat. In spite of criticisms of its environmental and distributional impact, this technology is widely credited with having had a favourable impact on nutrition, employment and incomes, albeit mainly in the areas of developing countries capable of reasonably assured irrigation. Subsequently, further breeding efforts have tried, but with less success, to extend these technologies to new crops and to rainfed and dryland areas.
More recently, significant changes have occurred in both the technology and the structure of research in agriculture. First, the advent of biotechnology, and in particular genetic engineering, in the last twenty years has vastly expanded the possibilities of what can be achieved in agricultural research (for example, introducing new genetic traits in plants). Secondly, while public investment in public research, at least through the CGIAR, has tended to stagnate in recent years, investment by the private sector has gone up rapidly.[175] Market forces have increasingly guided the direction and purpose of additional research spending.
Historically, systems for the protection of intellectual property were applied principally to mechanical inventions of one kind or another, or to artistic creations. The assignment of IPRs to living things is of relatively recent origin in developed countries. Vegetatively propagated plants were first made patentable in the US only in 1930. And the protection of plant varieties (or plant breeder’s rights - PBRs), a new form of intellectual property, only became widespread in the second half of the 20th Century. Thus systems for the protection of plants derive from the economic structure and circumstances of agriculture that prevailed in developed countries in this period. That such systems came into being reflected the growing interest of private breeders in protecting their intellectual property. Farmers have traditionally replanted, exchanged or sold seed from the previous years’ crop which means that breeders have difficulty in recouping the investments made in improved varieties through repeat sales. Patents or PBRs normally impose restrictions on farmers’ ability to sell grown seed (and in some cases to reuse it) and thus enhance the market for the breeder’s seed. Even in the developed countries, reuse of seeds remains quite common although for many crops annual purchase is now the rule. In developing countries the majority of farmers reuse, exchange or sell informally to neighbours, and annual purchase of new seed is relatively rare in most countries.
With the adoption of the TRIPS Agreement, developing countries have been obliged to adopt protection of plant varieties, by patents or by other means, without any serious consideration being given to whether such protection would be beneficial, both to producers and consumers, or its possible impact on food security. As with medicines, a crucial issue is whether and how intellectual property protection can help promote research and innovation relevant to the needs of developing countries and poor people. And we also need to ask how IP protection affects the cost and access of farmers to the seeds and other inputs they need.
If the aim of plant variety protection is to provide incentives to breeders, one of the questions that arises is how the contribution of farmers to the conservation and development of plant genetic resources should be recognised and preserved. Until formal breeding programmes were introduced, varietal and cultural improvements depended on a process of selection and experimentation by farmers. Formal breeding programmes have since utilised those varieties and knowledge in order to develop improved varieties of higher productivity, or with other desirable characteristics. The question is whether this contribution of farmers to conservation and innovation should be either protected or rewarded. Building on the principles embodied in the Convention on Biological Diversity (CBD), which we discuss in the next chapter, the new International Treaty on Plant Genetic Resources (ITPGR) seeks to establish principles for facilitating access to plant genetic resources and establishing fair and equitable mechanisms of benefit sharing.
In this chapter, we address the following questions:
· Can intellectual property protection on plants and genetic resources help to generate the technologies required by farmers in developing countries?
· Will IP protection affect the access of farmers to technologies they need?
· How could the intellectual property system contribute to the principles of access and benefit sharing enshrined in the CBD and the ITPGR?
Under TRIPS, countries may exclude from patentability plants and animals and essentially biological processes for producing them, but not microorganisms. And they are required to apply some form of protection, either by patents or a sui generis system to plant varieties.
There are many legal complexities about definitions arising from the wording of TRIPS, such as the exact meaning of a plant variety, a “microorganism” or an essentially biological process. But it is important to note here that TRIPS does not mention whether or not genes should be patentable, whether derived from plants humans, or animals. The issue raised by TRIPS is what constitutes an invention in relation to genetic material. For instance, should genetic material identified in nature be patentable on the grounds that isolating and purifying it differentiates it from an unpatentable discovery? This is a matter for national legislation. The only specific requirement, other than for microorganisms, is that plant varieties be protected.
Some people object altogether to the patenting of life forms on ethical grounds, considering that the private ownership of substances created by nature is wrong, and inimical to cultural values in different parts of the world. The sequencing of the human genome also raises specific concerns. We recognise these concerns, which we discuss further in Chapter 6 in the context of designing patent systems. The ethical and legal issues in respect of patenting DNA are discussed in a recent report of the Nuffield Council on Bioethics.[176] Our task here is to consider the practical and economic consequences of patenting in agriculture and how this affects the livelihoods of poor people and the implications for policy.
Intellectual property protection can be conferred in relation to plant materials in a number of ways:
· The US model of plant patents, which are distinct from normal (utility) patents
· Through allowing normal patents on plants or parts thereof, such as cells
· Through patenting plant varieties as is the practice in the US and in few other countries (for example, not in the EU)
· Through applying a sui generis form of plant variety protection (PVP), such as plant breeders’ rights (as in the EU or the US) or other modalities.
· Through allowing patents on DNA sequences, and gene constructs including the gene, plants transformed with those constructs, the seed and progeny of those plants.
In addition, patents are widely used to protect the technologies which are employed in research on plant genomics.[177]
Apart from the use of patents and PVP, the intellectual property in plants can be appropriated by technological means. For instance, crops such as commercial hybrid[178] maize cannot be reused if hybrid yield and vigour are to be maintained. This characteristic of some hybrids confers a natural form of protection by which seed companies can more readily capture a return on their investment through repeat seed sales. By contrast, other types of seed variety can be replanted each year without deterioration in yield, so that farmers may replant their own seed without repurchasing. The Green Revolution varieties were of this nature, which is one reason why they were so successful. It is only more recently that hybrid varieties of rice and then wheat have been developed. Genetic Use Restriction Technologies (known as GURTs) is a term used to describe different forms of controlling the action of genes in plants. The so-called “terminator” technology, which would render the seed sterile so that it is not physically possible to grow a second crop,[179] is well known but other characteristics can also be controlled, either for agronomic or commercial reasons. The effect of technological protection is similar to that of IP protection, but possibly cheaper and certainly more effective in the sense that it is self-enforcing.
As compared to medical research, there is a great deal more agricultural R&D undertaken by, and of relevance to, developing countries. For instance it is estimated that in 1995, total expenditure by the public sector on agricultural research in developing countries, although unevenly distributed, amounted to $11.5 billion (at 1993 international dollar values) compared to the $10.2 billion spent in developed countries.[180] The great majority of research is conducted in the more technologically advanced developing countries in Asia and Latin America. Moreover, research expenditures by these countries grew at 5-7% annually between 1976 and 1996, while they stagnated in Africa.[181] By contrast, of worldwide private research expenditure totalling $11.5 billion, only $0.7 billion is attributable to developing countries.
This means that, globally, about one third of all agricultural R&D is spent in developing countries in marked contrast to the maximum of 5% estimated for health research for developing countries. Three points should be noted here. First, global R&D on agriculture is only a little more than half that estimated for health R&D.[182] Secondly, there is almost twice as much agricultural R&D in the public sector as the private sector. In medicine, expenditure by the private sector is proportionately larger, as we have seen. Thirdly, and partly as a result, the developing countries are relatively better served in the case of agricultural research.
Nevertheless current trends give cause for concern. Although the CGIAR spends only about $340 million per year, its role is strategically important. For instance, the CGIAR centres played a crucial role in the Green Revolution and now act as the guardian of the world’s largest collection of genetic resources of relevance to developing countries, which is the major source of crop improvements for the future. But funding for the CGIAR system, which is provided by the donor community, has fallen in real terms since 1990[183] and this threatens both its research effort and its ability to maintain its gene banks, or assist developing countries in maintaining their own collections. Indeed the FAO and CGIAR have launched an endowment specifically to ensure that these genetic materials across the world can be properly maintained.[184] While funding from the aid donor community is stagnating, the private sector is the dynamic element in agricultural R&D, but little of its effort is of direct relevance to poor farmers in developing countries.
The Impact of Plant Variety Protection
In this section we examine the evidence on the impact of plant variety protection (PVP) in developed and developing countries and what PVP systems might have to offer developing countries.
Most of the evidence relating to the impact of patent or plant variety protection on research is from developed countries, and even that is quite sparse. Before IP protection was introduced, private sector breeding initiatives focused on hybrid varieties, particularly of maize in the US, because inherent in these varieties is an element of “technological protection”. In the US a study from the 1980s suggested there was no evidence that total R&D activity had increased as a result of the introduction of PVP, although it appeared to have had some impact on soya beans, and perhaps wheat.[185] The latter crops also accounted for the majority of PVP certificates issued. There was also evidence that PVP was used as a marketing strategy for product differentiation and that it had contributed to the large number of mergers that took place in the seed industry. But the evidence is inconclusive, in particular because of the difficulty in isolating the effect of protection from other ongoing changes. Even now research spending on hybrid crops as a share of sales continues to exceed that on non-hybrid crops, which are the principal object of PVP.[186] A recent study found that PVP on wheat in the US had not contributed to increased investment in private sector wheat breeding, but may have done so in the public sector. Nor had it contributed to an increase in yields. But the share of wheat acreage sown to private varieties had increased markedly, reinforcing the suggestion that the main impact of PVP was as a marketing tool.[187]
A major study conducted in middle income developing countries[188] found little evidence of an increased range of plant material available to farmers or increased innovation as a result of PVP protection. Access to foreign genetic material had improved, but its use was sometimes subject to restrictions, for example on exports. Generally speaking, commercial farmers and the seed industry were perceived as the principal beneficiaries. Poor farmers had not benefited directly from protection, but could potentially be adversely affected by restrictions on seed saving and exchange in the future.
Under TRIPS, developing countries may choose an “effective sui generis” PVP system. A major decision is to identify a system that is suitable to their particular agricultural and socio-economic circumstances. The UPOV Convention (see Box 3.1) is one system which they may adopt, based on the legislation introduced in Europe and the US. A consideration is that it provides a ready made legislative framework, but a disadvantage is that it was designed with the commercialised farming systems of the developed countries in mind. There are therefore concerns expressed about the application of the UPOV model in developing countries, some of which apply to any form of PVP.
The criteria for awarding a PVP certificate involve lower thresholds than the standards required for patents. There are requirements for novelty and distinctness, but there is no equivalent of non-obviousness (inventive step) or utility (industrial applicability). Thus, PVP law allows breeders to protect varieties with very similar characteristics, which means the system tends to be driven by commercial considerations of product differentiation and planned obsolescence, rather than genuine improvements in agronomic traits.[189] Developing countries might consider raising the threshold, in particular so that protection is only given for significant or important innovations with particular characteristics that are deemed socially beneficial (for example, yield increases, or traits of nutritional value). Thus the criteria for distinctness may be strengthened, and also criteria formulated defining utility in terms of the objectives of agricultural policy. Alternatively, countries may decide to retain lower standards for certain categories of plant in order to facilitate access by nascent domestic breeding industries to PVP protection from which may flow commercial and export benefits.
Similarly, the requirement for uniformity (and stability) in UPOV type systems excludes local varieties developed by farmers that are more heterogeneous genetically, and less stable. But these characteristics are those that make them more adaptable and suited to the agro-ecological environments in which the majority of poor farmers live. Again it would be open to developing countries to devise systems that would offer protection for varieties that meet criteria suited to the circumstances and crops on which poor farmers depend. But such criteria may be difficult to devise, and the system costly to operate. And governments may consider that extending such a system would not play a positive role in the development of their farming systems.
Another concern is about the criterion for uniformity. While proponents argue that PVP, by stimulating the production of new varieties, actually increases biodiversity, others claim that the requirement for uniformity, and the certification of essentially similar varieties of crops, will add to uniformity of crops and loss of biodiversity. Of course this concern goes wider than PVP. Seed legislation in many countries imposes strict uniformity requirements, sometimes stricter than PVP legislation. Moreover similar concerns have arisen in respect of greater uniformity arising from the success of Green Revolution varieties, leading to greater susceptibility to disease and loss of on-field biodiversity. But, as plant breeding becomes an increasingly private sector activity, and new varieties displace traditional varieties on a large scale, there is the crucial issue of how genetic resources are to be conserved and maintained for possible future use, whether in fields or in “gene banks”.[190]
There may also be a need to differentiate standards of protection between different kinds of crop. For instance, countries with significant commercial and export sectors might adopt UPOV-type standards for the relevant crops in those sectors to encourage innovation and commercialisation. But they might adopt other standards for food crops grown by farmers to protect their practices of saving, trading and exchanging seeds, and informal systems of innovation. For instance, in Kenya PVP rights seem to have been predominantly applied for by the foreign-owned commercial exporters of flowers and vegetables to underpin commercialisation and exporting. This may be beneficial to the expansion of Kenya’s export industries and commercial agriculture, and indirectly to poor people. PVP may facilitate the availability of new varieties in Kenya (which might have been withheld in the absence of protection) but appears to play little part in stimulating local research. The system has not appeared to be very relevant to the direct concerns of Kenya’s poor farmers and the crops they grow.
Box 3.1. Union
Internationale pour la Protection des Obtentions Végétales/ International Union
for the Protection of New Varieties of Plants (UPOV)
The internationally recognised agreement on PVP
protection is UPOV. The UPOV
Convention dates from 1961, and has been revised thrice subsequently. Apart from South Africa, the first
developing countries to join UPOV were Uruguay and Argentina in 1994, when
there were 26 members in total. Since
1994, 24 further developing countries have joined UPOV. Although TRIPS only specifies that there should
be a sui generis regime, UPOV has
been an obvious choice as it provides an off-the shelf solution to developing
such legislation. In addition, pressure
has been put on various countries to join UPOV in the context of bilateral
trade agreements (for instance, the recently concluded Vietnam-US trade
agreement obliges both parties to be members of UPOV, of which the US is
already a member).
The purpose of the UPOV Convention is to ensure that
the member States of the Union acknowledge the achievements of breeders of new
plant varieties, by making available to them exclusive property right, on the
basis of a set of uniform and clearly defined principles.
As UPOV has been revised successively (1978 and 1991),
the scope and length of protection has been extended. The minimum period of protection increased to 20 years (25 years
for vines and trees) in the 1991 version (from 15 and 20 previously). Unlike patents, the criteria for protection
do not involve an inventive step as such.
Rather, to be eligible, varieties must only be distinctive, uniform and
stable (DUS in the jargon) and novel (in terms of prior
commercialisation).
The 1978 Act allowed breeders to use protected
varieties as a source for new varieties, which could then be protected and
marketed themselves. The 1991 Act has preserved the breeders’ exception, but
the right of the breeder extends to varieties which are “essentially derived”
from the protected variety, which cannot be marketed without the permission of
the holder of the original variety.
The 1978 Act provided the breeder with protection in
respect of production for the sale of seed, its offer for sale and its
commercialisation(Article 5 (1)) and it therefore implicitly allowed farmers to
replant and exchange the seed (although this right is not spelt out). The 1991 Act is more restrictive of the
rights of farmers. The right of the
breeder now extends to production or reproduction, in addition to the marketing
of propagated or harvested material (Article 14 (1)). This is mitigated by an optional farmers’ exception which allows
“farmers to use
for propagating purposes, on their own holdings, the product of the harvest
which they have obtained by planting, on their own holdings, the protected
variety or [an essentially derived variety].” (Article 15 (2)).[191]
Thus developing countries should consider basing their PVP legislation on a realistic appreciation of how it could benefit their agricultural development and food security, taking account also of agriculture’s role in generating exports, foreign exchange and employment. In particular they need to consider possible modifications to the UPOV model to adapt it to their circumstances.[192] A number of countries have passed or are considering legislation which incorporates elements described above.[193]
An important
aspect of sui generis systems is the
scope of the farmers’ exception. Unlike patents, PVP legislation
generally allows an exception, as in UPOV 1978, which permits farmers to reuse
on their own holding harvested seeds without the permission of the
rightsholder. In the US, this exception was expanded to allow limited
sale of harvested crops for seed purposes to other farmers. And, in the
developing world, in the absence of legal rules, farmers exchange and sell
their seeds informally. As we have noted, this is a practice which
is still very widespread amongst poor farmers in developing countries, and
even still common in developed countries. These systems of sale and
exchange are an important mechanism by which farmers have traditionally
selected and improved their own varieties, and the restriction of this right
may impede this process of improvement. Although UPOV (1991) permits
nations to allow farmers to reuse their own crop for seed purposes on their own
holdings, it does not allow for informal sale or exchange. In contrast,
TRIPS only requires that there should be some form of IP protection for plant
varieties, and does not define in any way the exceptions that may be provided
to the rights of owners of protected varieties.
Thus countries and organisations have experimented with a number of alternatives in this area. For instance, the OAU (now the African Union) has produced model legislation which it recommends African countries adapt in their own legislation. This provides for the right to save, use, multiply and process farm-saved seed, but not to sell it on a commercial scale.[194] The Indian government, which has recently decided to seek admission to UPOV, has incorporated in its PVP legislation (2002) a clause (39 (1) (iv)) that states:
“a farmer shall be deemed to be entitled to save, use,
sow, re-sow, exchange, share or sell his farm produce including seed of a
variety protected under this Act in the same manner as he was entitled to
before the coming into force of this Act:
Provided that the farmer shall not be entitled to sell
branded seed of a variety protected under this Act.”[195]
The breeders’ exception under PVP also differs from patent law in that breeders may, without authorisation, use a protected variety as the basis for breeding another variety (which itself may then gain protection). Thus PVP provides less protection than patents, and as we have argued little incentive for research, but correspondingly is less restrictive of incremental follow-on innovation than patents. Again developing countries are free to choose exactly what exceptions they provide. At one extreme, PVP could be conferred as a superior kind of seed certificate or seal giving the holder the sole rights to sell seed with this seal. But there would be no rights to protect subsequent use or sale of the seed, as long as it was not sold under the certificate. This right would be superior to a trademark or seed certificate, but would not restrict subsequent reuse of harvested material in any way. Such a system might be a way to tailor the PVP system to the needs of poor farmers, but it would offer less incentive for breeders.[196]
The Impact of Patents
Patents on plant varieties, as such, are only allowed in the US, Japan and Australia, and are most frequent in the US. The 1930 US Act introduced a special kind of Plant Patent for vegetatively propagated materials, but in the US standard utility patents can also now be granted on plant varieties. Patents are the strongest form of intellectual property protection in the sense that they normally allow the rightsholder to exert the greatest control over the use of patented material by limiting the rights of farmers to sell, or reuse seed they have grown, or other breeders to use the seed (or patented intermediate technologies) for further research and breeding purposes. However, patent law can provide for exceptions similar to those in PVP systems. For example, the EU Biotechnology Directive, while not permitting the patenting of plant varieties, provides for a farmer’s exception where a patent on genetic material would otherwise prevent reuse on the farm. It also contains a provision for compulsory licensing, subject to certain conditions, where a breeder’s use of material would otherwise infringe the patent right.[197]
In the US, the patenting of plant varieties is particularly important because, with appropriate claims in the patent, the holder of the patented variety can prevent others from using it for breeding purposes. This is a significant difference from PVP. Proving that a new variety meets the criteria for patentability is more difficult and more costly than obtaining plant variety protection, where the criteria for protection are lower. Patent protection is also frequently obtained through a broad patent which claims the gene, the vector or carrier for effecting the transformation and so on, which may cover a number of potential varieties or crops incorporating the gene. For practical purposes this may have the same effect as patenting the whole plant, because the patent normally extends to “all material…in which the product is incorporated”.[198]
Whatever the incentives provided by patenting, market forces will tend to direct research efforts by the private sector to where there is the most substantial potential return. However, in contrast to medicines, there is the potential for companies to become attracted to crops that are widely grown in developing countries. The investment costs are correspondingly lower than for medical research, and the potential markets correspondingly larger. For instance rice, where the value of production in India alone exceeds that of the US maize market, has hitherto been a crop where breeding has been the preserve of the national or international public sector (principally the CGIAR). Since then the private sector has become increasingly interested in rice research. Monsanto and Syngenta have worked on sequencing the rice genome of two major rice varieties. The number of patents relating to rice issued annually in the US has risen from less than 100 in 1995 to over 600 in 2000.[199]
So far about 80% of trials of transgenic crops have occurred in developed countries, where three quarters of the world’s GM crops are grown. The breeding strategies of the multinationals have been naturally oriented to the needs of developed world markets, and the commercial sectors of middle income developing countries (for example, Brazil, Argentina or China). The development of genetic traits such as herbicide tolerance has been determined principally by the search for commercial advantage, rather than for characteristics useful to poor farmers in developing countries. But companies are introducing GM varieties which, although controversial both in developed and developing countries, are considered by some developing countries to be of potential benefit to them (for example, the Bt gene which confers insect resistance).[200] Bt Cotton or Bt maize is now grown in at least five developing countries, and other countries may be interested, if they can resolve environmental concerns. For instance, India has recently approved the planting of Bt Cotton. Companies have also donated technologies of relevance to developing countries (for example, through royalty free licences), including those related to vitamin A enriched rice (Golden Rice) and cassava. Some companies have published scientific articles based on their genomic research, but have aroused controversy by not depositing the raw data in public databanks. Negotiations about the deposit in public databanks have been complicated by the companies’ desire to limit access to components of data with the greatest potential commercial value.[201]
Thus there is the potential for agricultural technologies developed by the private sector to spill over to the benefit of the commercial sectors in developing countries. But if the Green Revolution which was developed and applied with public sector funding failed to reach effectively poor farmers living in agro-ecologically diverse rainfed environments, it is apparent that biotechnology-related research led by the private sector led will be even less likely to do so. For that, more public sector research specifically oriented to such farmers will be required. In 1998, the CGIAR system spent $25 million on such research compared to the $1.26 billion invested by Monsanto.[202]
Apart from the problem of incentives for research relevant to poor farmers, there is evidence that patents, and to some extent PVP, have played a part in the major consolidation of the global seed and agricultural input industries. The consolidation appears to be driven by technological change, with an objective of vertical and horizontal integration so that the appropriability of investment in research can be maximized through better control of distribution channels, including those of complementary agricultural inputs (such as herbicides).
Companies acquire patent rights to protect their own investment in research, and to prevent the encroachment of others. But by the same token, other companies’ patent rights can impede one’s own research. For instance, there are several hundred overlapping patent rights for the Bt technology, and at least four companies obtained patents that cover Bt-transformed maize.[203] Recently, Syngenta filed two law suits in the US against a number of its competitors alleging infringement of several of its patents relating to this technology, although the companies involved have been using these technologies, and selling seeds incorporating them, for several years.[204] Cross licensing,[205] or strategic alliances, can also be used as mechanisms to overcome problems of conflicting patents,[206] but merger or acquisition may be the most effective means of obtaining the freedom to use required technologies in a particular field of research. All of these approaches, not just the last, reduce competition. And the major multinational agrochemical companies, with their growing control over essential proprietary technologies, also represent a formidable barrier to the entry of innovative start-ups.[207] In the 1980s, the university and public sector accounted for 50% of the total of granted US patents relating to Bt. By 1994, independent biotechnology companies and individuals held 77%, but by 1999 the big six companies (which became five with the merger of the agricultural arms of AstraZeneca and Novartis to form Syngenta) held 67%. Moreover, the growing control of these companies was demonstrated by the fact that 75% of their Bt patents in 1999 had been obtained by the acquisition of smaller biotechnology and seed companies.[208]
In developing countries, there is evidence of similar trends with an extremely rapid process of merger and acquisition by the multinational companies. For instance, in Brazil, following the introduction of plant variety protection in 1997 (but presumably also related to the expected permission to grow GM crops), Monsanto increased its share of the maize seed market from 0% to 60% between 1997 and 1999. It acquired three locally based firms (including Cargill as the result of an international deal), while Dow and Agrevo (now Aventis) also increased their market share by acquisition. Only one Brazilian-owned firm remained with a 5% market share.[209] This trend appears widespread in developing countries.[210]
Thus, the speed of concentration in the sector raises serious competition issues. There are considerable dangers to food security if the technologies are overpriced to the exclusion of small farmers, or there is no alternative source of new technologies, particularly from the public sector. Further, the increase in concentration, and the conflicting patent claims when both the public and private sectors have patented plant technologies, may have had an inhibiting effect on research. In the private sector the response has been alliances or acquisitions, but a problem for the public sector is how to access the technologies they need to undertake research without infringing IP rights and, if they develop new technologies, the terms on which they may be made available. A recent review published by the US Department of Agriculture concludes that “whether the current intellectual property regime is stimulating or hampering research is unclear”.[211] We return to this subject in Chapter 6.
Thus developing countries have possibly three options for meeting their obligation to protect plant varieties under TRIPS. They may adopt one or a combination of the following:
· UPOV style legislation based on the 1978 or 1991 Convention (although they may now only join the 1991 Convention)
· Another form of sui generis system, including or not landraces
· Patents on plant varieties
Our reservations about the possible impact of patents apply not just to patents on plant varieties but also to plants and animals in general. At present there appears to be little evidence that providing patent protection for biotechnology-related inventions is really in the interests of the majority of developing countries which have little or no capability in this technology. We would therefore recommend that maximum use be made of the possibilities under TRIPS of excluding such inventions from patent protection. Even where TRIPS requires patent protection to be available, for example in respect of microorganisms, there is still scope for developing countries to restrict the scope of protection. In particular, in the absence of any universally recognised definition of what constitutes a “microorganism”, developing countries remain free to adopt a credible definition that limits the range of material covered.[212]
Developing countries should generally not provide patent protection for plants and animals, as is allowed under Article 27.3(b) of TRIPS, because of the restrictions patents may place on use of seed by farmers and researchers. Rather they should consider different forms of sui generis systems for plant varieties.
Those developing countries with limited technological
capacity should restrict the application of patenting in agricultural
biotechnology consistent with TRIPS, and they should adopt a restrictive
definition of the term “microorganism”.
Countries
that have, or wish to develop, biotechnology-related industries may wish to
provide certain types of patent protection in this area. If they do so, specific exceptions to the
exclusive rights, for plant breeding and research, should be established. The extent to which patent rights extend to
the progeny or multiplied product of the patented invention should also be
examined and a clear exception provided for farmers to reuse seeds.
The continuing review of Article 27.3(b) of TRIPS
should also preserve the right of countries not to grant patents for plants and
animals, including genes and genetically modified plants and animals, as well
as to develop sui generis regimes for
the protection of plant varieties that suit their agricultural systems. Such regimes should permit access to the
protected varieties for further research and breeding, and provide at least for
the right of farmers to save and plant-back seed, including the possibility of
informal sale and exchange.
Because of
the growing concentration in the seed industry, public sector research on
agriculture, and its international component, should be strengthened and better
funded. The objective should be to
ensure that research is oriented to the needs of poor farmers; that public
sector varieties are available to provide competition for private sector
varieties; and that the world’s plant genetic resource heritage is
maintained. In addition, this is an
area in which nations should consider the use of competition law to respond to
the high level of concentration in the private sector.
ACCESS TO PLANT GENETIC RESOURCES AND
FARMERS’ RIGHTS
Introduction
As noted above, a major issue of importance to the future of agricultural research is the conservation of genetic resources held in fields and in national and international collections, along with guaranteed access for researchers on terms that recognise the contribution made by farmers in the developing world in conserving, improving and making available these resources.
The foundation for international action to ensure the conservation, use and availability of plant genetic resources was the FAO Undertaking on Plant Genetic Resources agreed in 1983. Subsequently, the concept of Farmers’ Rights[213] arose in debates in the FAO where it was recognised that there was an imbalance between the IP rights afforded to breeders of modern plant varieties and the rights of farmers who were responsible for supplying the plant genetic resources from which such varieties were mainly derived. A second concern was the consistency between making available plant genetic resources as the common heritage of mankind, and the taking out of private IP rights on varieties derived from them.
In 1989 the FAO agreed to recognise these concerns by incorporating Farmers’ Rights “arising from the past, present and future contributions of farmers in conserving, improving, and making available plant genetic resources, particularly those in the centres of origin/ diversity” in the Undertaking.[214] Farmers’ Rights were to be implemented through an International Fund for Plant Genetic Resources, which would finance relevant activities, particularly in developing countries. Subsequently the FAO agreed that “Plant Breeders' Rights, as provided for under UPOV…are not incompatible with the International Undertaking”, a choice of words that reflected the continuing ambivalence felt by some developing countries about the underlying consistency between the Undertaking and UPOV.[215]
Following the agreement of the CBD in 1992, it was on this basis that the process of transforming the Undertaking into the Treaty (ITPGR), finally agreed in 2001, was undertaken.[216] The ITPGR has the specific objective of facilitating access to plant genetic resources held by contracting parties, and those in international collections, for the common good, recognising that these are an indispensable raw material for crop genetic improvement, and that many countries depend on genetic resources which have originated elsewhere. This represents an implementation of the CBD principles taking account of the specific characteristics of plant genetic resources. Most varieties now in existence, in particular those derived from public breeding programmes, contain genetic material from many sources, often derived from genetic material in gene banks, which themselves may have diverse origins.
The ITPGR also recognises the contribution of farmers in conserving, improving and making available these resources, and that this contribution is the basis of Farmers’ Rights. It does not limit in any form whatsoever rights that farmers may enjoy under national law to save, use, exchange and sell farm-saved seed. It also sets out the right to participate in decision making about, and to derive fair and equitable benefits from, the use of these resources (see Box 3.2).
The ITPGR leaves it entirely up to national governments to implement farmers’ rights (paragraph 9.2). Thus, implementing specific Farmers’ Rights is not an international obligation like that imposed under provisions in TRIPS.
The rationale for Farmers’ Rights combines arguments about equity and economics. Plant breeders and the world at large benefit from the conservation and development of plant genetic resources undertaken by farmers, but farmers are not recompensed for the economic value they have contributed. Farmers’ Rights may be seen as a means of providing incentives for farmers to continue to provide services of conservation and maintenance of biodiversity. As noted, the protection of plant varieties contains an inherent tendency to encourage uniformity and reduce biodiversity, to which the traditional practices of farmers are an essential counterweight. Farmers should be supported in recognition of the economic value they conserve, which is not recognised in the market system, and is to some extent threatened by technical change and the extension of plant breeders’ protection. Moreover, the extension of intellectual property protection does carry the risk of restricting farmers’ rights to reuse, exchange and sell seed, the very practices which form the basis of their traditional role in conservation and development.
9.1 The Contracting Parties recognize the enormous
contribution that the local and indigenous communities and farmers of all
regions of the world, particularly those in the centres of origin and crop
diversity, have made and will continue to make for the conservation and
development of plant genetic resources which constitute the basis of food and
agriculture production throughout the world.
9.2 The Contracting Parties agree that the
responsibility for realizing Farmers’ Rights, as they relate to plant genetic
resources for food and agriculture, rests with national governments. In
accordance with their needs and priorities, each Contracting Party should, as
appropriate, and subject to its national legislation, take measures to protect
and promote Farmers’ Rights, including:
(a)
protection of traditional knowledge relevant to plant genetic resources for
food and agriculture;
(b) the
right to equitably participate in sharing benefits arising from the utilization
of plant genetic resources for food and agriculture; and
(c) the
right to participate in making decisions, at the national level, on matters
related to the conservation and sustainable use of plant genetic resources for
food and agriculture.
9.3 Nothing in this Article shall be interpreted to
limit any rights that farmers have to save, use, exchange and sell farm-saved
seed/propagating material, subject to national law and as appropriate.
Farmers’ Rights are not an intellectual property right, but they need to be viewed as an important counterbalance to the rights accorded to breeders in the formal sector under PVP or patents. However, defining how to implement these rights at national level is complex, as we discuss in the next chapter in the context of CBD. The Treaty provides for a financing mechanism to be set up, financed by contributions and the share of the proceeds of commercialisation, which will enable the implementation of agreed plans and programmes for farmers “who conserve and sustainably utilise plant genetic resources for food and agriculture”.[217]
Under the Treaty, countries have agreed to provide facilitated access to plant genetic resources from an agreed list of crops listed in an annex, which are important for food security. By signing the Treaty, governments agree to put such resources under their direct control into the “Multilateral System”. They will also encourage institutions, not under their direct control, to do likewise. Of particular importance is the large collection of genetic material of interest to developing countries under the aegis of the CGIAR, but there are of course many national collections of worldwide importance in both developed and developing countries.
With regard to IPRs, the potentially contentious part of the treaty is that referring to the protection of resources accessed from the Multilateral System. As finally agreed the Treaty states:
“Recipients shall not claim any intellectual property
or other rights that limit the facilitated access to the plant genetic
resources for food and agriculture, or their genetic parts or components, in
the form received from the Multilateral System;”[218]
This wording is inevitably a diplomatic compromise, reflecting a desire on the part of many developing countries to avoid a limitation on access being imposed by the grant of IP rights, and of some developed countries to allow patenting of genetic material according to existing criteria applied nationally. The crucial words “in the form received” mean that material received cannot be patented as such, but they do allow patents to be taken out on modifications (however defined) to that material.
The compromise
wording clearly excludes the patenting of seeds as obtained from a seed
bank. But the extent to which patents
can be taken out on a gene isolated from that material is controversial. During the negotiation of the Treaty, some
countries were of the opinion that this article should be read as precluding
such patenting. Others thought that the
isolated form of a gene (for which a function has also been determined) is
different than the “form received” and, hence, should be patentable. Thus the wording raises the important
general issue of what are the appropriate rules for patenting genetic material,
both for developed and developing countries.
This revolves around the nature of the inventive step required for
patenting, the nature of the claims for the invented use of that material, and
the extent to which those claims might limit use of the underlying genetic
material. We discuss this further in
Chapter 6.
The Treaty has also established an important principle in that any user of material will sign a standard Material Transfer Agreement (MTA),[219], to be devised by the Governing Body of the Treaty, which will incorporate the conditions for access agreed in the Treaty (paragraph 12.3) and provide for benefit sharing of the proceeds of any commercialisation arising from the material through a Fund established under the Treaty. This significantly goes beyond the provisions of CBD in suggesting a concrete mechanism for benefit sharing, based on multilateral rather than bilateral arrangements.
Developed and developing countries should accelerate
the process of ratification of the FAO International Treaty on Plant Genetic
Resources for Food and Agriculture and should, in particular, implement the
Treaty’s provisions relating to:
·
Not granting IPR protection of any material transferred in the
framework of the multilateral system, in the form received.
·
Implementation of Farmers’ Rights at the national level, including
(a) protection of traditional knowledge relevant to plant genetic resources for
food and agriculture; (b) the right to equitably participate in sharing
benefits arising from the utilisation of plant genetic resources for food and
agriculture; (c) the right to participate in making decisions, at the national
level, on matters related to the conservation and sustainable use of plant
genetic resources for food and agriculture.
Human communities have always generated, refined and passed on knowledge from generation to generation. Such “traditional” knowledge”[220] is often an important part of their cultural identities. Traditional knowledge has played, and still plays, a vital role in the daily lives of the vast majority of people. Traditional knowledge is essential to the food security and health of millions of people in the developing world. In many countries, traditional medicines provide the only affordable treatment available to poor people. In developing countries, up to 80% of the population depend on traditional medicines to help meet their healthcare needs.[221] In addition, knowledge of the healing properties of plants has been the source of many modern medicines. As we note in Chapter 3, the use and continuous development by local farmers of plant varieties and the sharing and diffusion of these varieties and the knowledge associated with them play an essential role in agricultural systems in developing countries.
Only recently, however, has the international community sought to recognise and protect traditional knowledge. In 1981, WIPO and UNESCO adopted a model law on folklore. In 1989 the concept of Farmers’ Rights was introduced by the FAO into its International Undertaking on Plant Genetic Resources and in 1992 the Convention on Biological Diversity (CBD) highlighted the need to promote and preserve traditional knowledge.[222] In spite of these efforts which have spanned two decades, final and universally acceptable solutions for the protection and promotion of traditional knowledge have not yet emerged.
The CBD also set out principles governing access to genetic resources and the knowledge associated with them, and the sharing of benefits arising from such access. We therefore consider the relationship between the IP system and the access and benefit sharing principles of the CBD in the context of both knowledge, traditional or otherwise, and genetic resources.
We also consider here, although it is largely a separate issue, whether Geographical Indications (GIs) have a role to play in promoting development, and the issues relevant to developing countries in the current discussions on this issue in the TRIPS Council.
Thus in this Chapter we examine the following questions:
·
What is the nature of traditional knowledge and folklore and what do we mean by its
protection?
·
How can the existing IP system be used to protect and
promote traditional knowledge?
·
What modifications of the IP system might improve its
protection?
·
How can the IP system support the principles of access and
benefit sharing enshrined in the Convention on Biological Diversity (CBD)?
·
Is the protection of Geographical Indications important
for developing countries?
A number of cases relating to traditional knowledge have attracted international attention. As a result, the issue of traditional knowledge has been brought to the fore of the general debate surrounding intellectual property. These cases involve what is often referred to as “biopiracy” (See Boxes 4.1 and 4.2). The examples of turmeric, neem and ayahuasca illustrate the issues that can arise when patent protection is granted to inventions relating to traditional knowledge which is already in the public domain. In these cases, invalid patents were issued because the patent examiners were not aware of the relevant traditional knowledge. In another example, a patent was granted on a plant species called Hoodia. Here, the issue is not whether the patent should or should not have been granted, but rather on whether the local people known as the San, who had nurtured the traditional knowledge underpinning the invention, were entitled to receive a fair share of any benefits arising from commercialisation.
Box 4.1 Biopiracy
There is no accepted definition of “biopiracy.” The
Action Group on Erosion, Technology and Concentration (ETC Group) defines it as “the appropriation of the knowledge and
genetic resources of farming and indigenous communities by individuals or
institutions seeking exclusive monopoly control (usually patents or plant
breeders' rights) over these resources and knowledge.”
The following have been described as “biopiracy”:
a)
The granting of ‘wrong’ patents.
These are patents granted for inventions that are either not novel or
are not inventive having regard to traditional knowledge already in the public
domain. Such patents may be granted due either to oversights during the
examination of the patent or simply because the patent examiner did not have
access to the knowledge. This may be because it is written down but not
accessible using the tools available to the examiner, or because it is
unwritten knowledge. A WIPO led initiative to document and classify traditional
knowledge seeks to address some of these problems.
b)
The granting of ‘right’ patents. Patents may be correctly granted
according to national law on inventions derived from a community’s traditional
knowledge or genetic resources. It could be argued this constitutes “biopiracy”
on the following grounds:
·
Patenting
standards are too low. Patents are
allowed, for instance, for inventions which amount to little more than
discoveries. Alternatively, the national patent regime (for example, as in the
US) may not recognise some forms of public disclosure of traditional knowledge
as prior art.[223]
·
Even if the
patent represents a genuine invention, however defined, no arrangements may
have been made to obtain the prior informed consent (PIC)[224]
of the communities providing the knowledge or resource, and for sharing the
benefits of commercialisation to reward them appropriately in accordance with
the principles of the CBD.
Box 4.2 Controversial Patent Cases involving
Traditional Knowledge and Genetic Resources
The Turmeric Case
Turmeric (Curcuma
longa) is a plant of the ginger family yielding saffron-coloured rhizomes
used as a spice for flavouring Indian cooking. It also has properties that make
it an effective ingredient in medicines, cosmetics and as a colour dye. As a
medicine, it is traditionally used to heal wounds and rashes.
·
In 1995, two
Indian nationals at the University of Mississippi Medical Centre were granted
US patent no. 5,401,504 on "use of turmeric in wound healing".
·
The Indian Council
of Scientific and Industrial Research (CSIR) requested the US Patent and
Trademark Office (USPTO) to re-examine the patent.
·
CSIR argued
that turmeric has been used for thousands of years for healing wounds and
rashes and therefore its medicinal use was not novel.
·
Their claim
was supported by documentary evidence of traditional knowledge, including an
ancient Sanskrit text and a paper published in 1953 in the Journal of the
Indian Medical Association.
·
Despite
arguments by the patentees, the USPTO upheld the CSIR objections and revoked
the patent.
Observations: The turmeric case was a landmark case as
it was the first time that a patent based on the traditional knowledge of a
developing country had been successfully challenged. The legal costs incurred by
India in this case have been calculated by the Indian Government to be about at
US $10,000.
The Neem Case
Neem (Azadirachta indica) is a tree from India
and other parts of South and Southeast Asia.
It is now planted across the tropics because of its properties as a
natural medicine, pesticide and fertilizer. Neem extracts can be used
against hundreds of pests and fungal diseases that attack food crops; the oil
extracted from its seeds is used to treat colds and flu; and mixed in soap, it
is believed to offer low cost relief from malaria, skin diseases and even
meningitis.
·
In 1994 the
EPO granted European Patent No. 0436257 to the US Corporation W.R. Grace and
USDA for a “method for controlling fungi on plants by the aid of a hydrophobic
extracted neem oil”.
·
In 1995 a
group of international NGOs and representatives of Indian farmers filed a legal
opposition against the patent.
·
They
submitted evidence that the fungicidal effect of extracts of neem seeds had
been known and used for centuries in Indian agricultural to protect crops, and
thus was the invention claimed in EP257 was not novel.
·
In 1999 the
EPO determined that according to the evidence “all features of the present
claim have been disclosed to the public prior to the patent application… and [the
patent] was considered not to involve an inventive step”.
·
The patent
was revoked by the EPO in 2000.
The Ayahuasca Case
For generations, shamans of indigenous tribes
throughout the Amazon Basin have processed the bark of Banisteriopsis caapi to produce a ceremonial drink known as
"ayahuasca". The shamans use ayahuasca (which means "vine of the
soul") in religious and healing ceremonies to diagnose and treat
illnesses, meet with spirits, and divine the future.
An American, Loren Miller obtained US Plant Patent
5,751 in June 1986, granting him rights over an alleged variety of B. caapi he had called "Da
Vine". The patent description stated that the “plant was discovered
growing in a domestic garden in the Amazon rain-forest of South America.” The
patentee claimed that Da Vine represented a new and distinct variety of B. caapi, primarily because of the
flower colour.
The Coordinating Body of Indigenous Organizations of
the Amazon Basin (COICA) – an umbrella organisation representing over 400
indigenous groups – learned of the patent in 1994. On their behalf the Center
for International Environmental Law (CIEL) filed a re-examination request on
the patent. CIEL protested that a review of the prior art revealed that Da Vine
was neither new nor distinct. They argued also that the granting of the patent
would be contrary to the public and morality aspects of the Patent Act because
of the sacred nature of Banisteriopsis
caapi throughout the Amazon region.
Extensive, new prior art was presented by CIEL, and in November 1999,
the USPTO rejected the patent claim agreeing that Da Vine was not
distinguishable from the prior art presented by CIEL and therefore the patent
should never have been issued. However, further arguments by the patentee
persuaded the USPTO to reverse its decision and announce in early 2001 that the
patent should stand.
Observation: Because of the date of filing of the
patent, it was not covered by the new rules in the US on inter partes
re-examination. CIEL were therefore unable to comment on the arguments made by
the patentee that led to the patent being upheld.
The San, who live around the Kalahari Desert in
southern Africa, have traditionally eaten the Hoodia cactus to stave off hunger
and thirst on long hunting trips. In
1937, a Dutch anthropologist studying the San noted this use of Hoodia. Scientists at the South African Council for
Scientific and Industrial Research (CSIR) only recently found his report and
began studying the plant.
In 1995 CSIR patented Hoodia’s appetite-suppressing
element (P57). In 1997 they licensed P57 to the UK
biotech company, Phytopharm. In
1998, the pharmaceutical company Pfizer acquired the rights to develop and
market P57 as a potential slimming drug and cure for obesity (a market worth
more than Ł6 billion), from Phytopharm for up to $32 million in royalty and
milestone payments.
On hearing of possible exploitation of their
traditional knowledge, the San People threatened legal action against the CSIR
on grounds of “biopiracy.” They claimed
that their traditional knowledge had been stolen, and CSIR
had failed to comply with the rules of the Convention on Biodiversity, which
requires the prior informed consent of all stakeholders, including the original
discoverers and users.
Phytopharm had conducted extensive enquiries but were
unable to find any of the “knowledge holders”. The remaining San were
apparently at the time living in a tented camp 1500 miles from their tribal
lands. The CSIR claimed they had planned to
inform the San of the research and share the benefits, but first wanted to make
sure the drug proved successful.
In March 2002, an understanding was reached between
the CSIR and the San whereby the San, recognised as the custodians of
traditional knowledge associated with the Hoodia plant, will receive a share of
any future royalties. Although the San
are likely to receive only a very small percentage of eventual sales, the
potential size of the market means that the sum involved could still be
substantial. The drug is unlikely to
reach the market before 2006, and may yet fail as it progresses through
clinical trials.
Observations: This case would appear to demonstrate that with
goodwill on all sides, mutually acceptable arrangements for access and benefit
sharing can be agreed. The importance of intellectual property in securing
future benefits appears to have been recognised by all parties including the
San.
Partly as a result of these well known cases, many developing countries, holders of traditional knowledge, and campaigning organisations are pressing in a multitude of fora for traditional knowledge to be better protected. Such pressure has led, for example, to the creation of an Intergovernmental Committee on Intellectual Property and Genetic Resources, Traditional Knowledge and Folklore in WIPO. The protection of traditional knowledge and folklore is also being discussed within the framework of the CBD and in other international organisations such as UNCTAD, WHO, FAO and UNESCO.[225] In addition, the Doha WTO Ministerial Declaration highlighted the need for further work in the TRIPS Council on protecting traditional knowledge.[226]
How can traditional knowledge be defined? Whilst the vast majority of the knowledge is old in the sense that it has been handed down through the generations, it is continually refined and new knowledge developed, rather as the modern scientific process proceeds by continual incremental improvement rather than by major leaps forward. Indeed one of the speakers at our conference suggested that the term “folklore” be replaced by the more appropriate “expressions of culture” which represents living, functional traditions, rather than souvenirs of the past. Whilst most traditional knowledge and folklore is passed on orally, some of it, such as textile designs and Ayurveda medicinal knowledge, is codified. The groups that hold traditional knowledge are very diverse: individuals, groups or groups of communities may all be custodians. Such communities might be indigenous to the land or descendents of later settlers. The nature of the knowledge is also diverse: it covers, for example, literary, artistic or scientific works, song, dance and medical treatments and practices and agricultural technologies and techniques.
Whilst a number of definitions for traditional knowledge and folklore have been put forward, there is no widely acceptable definition for either of them. It is not only the broad scope of traditional knowledge that has confounded the debate so far. There is also some confusion about exactly what is meant by “protection” and its purpose. It should certainly not be equated directly with the use of the word “protection” in its IP sense. In its report on a series of fact-finding missions, WIPO[227] sought to summarise the concerns of traditional knowledge holders as follows:
· concern about the loss of traditional life styles and of traditional knowledge, and the reluctance of the younger members of the communities to carry forward traditional practices
· concern about the lack of respect for traditional knowledge and holders of traditional knowledge
· concern about the misappropriation of traditional knowledge including use of traditional knowledge without any benefit sharing, or use in a derogatory manner
· lack of recognition of the need to preserve and promote the further use of traditional knowledge.
Another source more succinctly classified these and other possible reasons for protecting traditional knowledge as:
· equity considerations – the custodians of traditional knowledge should receive fair compensation if the traditional knowledge leads to commercial gain
· conservation concerns – the protection of traditional knowledge contributes to the wider objective of conserving the environment, bio-diversity and sustainable agricultural practices
· preservation of traditional practices and culture – protection of traditional knowledge would be used to raise the profile of the knowledge and the people entrusted with it both within and outside communities
· prevention of appropriation by unauthorised parties or avoiding “biopiracy”
· promotion of its use and its importance to development.[228]
A single solution can hardly be expected to meet such a wide range of concerns and objectives. The type of measures required to prevent misappropriation may not be the same, indeed may not be compatible, with those needed to encourage the wider use of traditional knowledge. A multiplicity of complementary measures will almost certainly be required, many of which will be outside the field of intellectual property. Indeed, underlying the debate may be a much bigger issue such as the position of indigenous communities within the wider economy and society of the country in which they reside, and their access to or ownership of land they have traditionally inhabited. In that sense, concerns about the preservation of traditional knowledge, and the continued way of life of those holding such knowledge, may be symptomatic of the underlying problems that face these communities in the face of external pressures.
However, we intend to limit our consideration to how the intellectual property system might help address these concerns. Much has already been written on this subject and many international organisations, in particularly WIPO, have started to consider whether the existing system of intellectual property has a role to play or whether new forms of protection will be required.
As noted above, a large number of bodies including WIPO, the CBD, UNCTAD and WTO are discussing the protection of traditional knowledge. These debates have rightfully focused on understanding the issue rather than on developing international norms. Only with a deeper understanding and greater practical experience at national or regional level would it be realistic to develop an international system of protection for traditional knowledge. It is essential that all of the agencies considering the issue work together to avoid unnecessary duplication and to ensure that the debate includes as many different views as possible. In this respect it has been suggested to us that an organisation such as WIPO, which deals exclusively with intellectual property matters, may not be the most appropriate forum to consider traditional knowledge in all its aspects.[229] We believe however that no single body is likely to have the capacity, expertise or resources to handle all aspects of traditional knowledge. Indeed it is our view that a multiplicity of measures, only some of them IP related, will be necessary to protect, preserve and promote traditional knowledge.
There is much to gain at this early stage by
considering the issue in a number of fora, while ensuring coherent approaches
are developed and that effort is not duplicated.
Making
Use of the Existing IP System to Protect and Promote Traditional Knowledge
Examples are emerging which illustrate how the current intellectual property system can be utilised to commercialise traditional knowledge or prevent its misuse. For example, Aboriginal and Torres Strait Islander artists in Australia have obtained a national certification trademark.[230] Like any other trademark, this certification mark or Label of Authenticity is intended to help promote the marketing of their art and cultural products and deter the sale of products falsely claiming to be of Aboriginal origin.
In recent surveys of the existing protection of traditional knowledge and folklore, a number of countries have provided further examples of how IP tools have been utilised to promote and protect traditional knowledge and folklore.[231] These include the use of copyright protection in Canada to protect tradition-based creations including masks, totem poles and sound recordings of Aboriginal artists; the use of industrial designs to protect the external appearance of articles such as head dresses and carpets in Kazakhstan and the use of geographical indications to protect traditional products such as liquors, sauces and teas in Venezuela and Vietnam.
The ability to extend the life of trademarks indefinitely and the possibility of collective ownership of such rights suggest that they may be especially suitable for protecting traditional knowledge. This is also the case with geographical indications, which may be used to protect traditional products or crafts if particular characteristics of such products can be attributed to a particular geographical origin. However, trademarks and geographical indications can only prevent the use of the protected marks or indications; they do not protect the knowledge, or the technologies embracing that knowledge, as such.
Other IP rights, especially those
requiring some form of novelty or those with fairly limited periods of
protection, seem less appropriate for protecting traditional knowledge. Nevertheless it is clear from these surveys,
and indeed other research, that existing IPRs do have a role to play in
protecting traditional knowledge.
Whether that role is a significant one remains to be seen. Experience elsewhere would suggest that the
impact may not be great, not least because of the high cost of obtaining and
enforcing rights. If the majority of
small companies in developed countries have found the
intellectual property system, particularly the patent system, to be
unattractive,[232] then it
seems unlikely that local communities in developing countries, or individuals
within such communities, will derive much benefit.
Sui
Generis Protection of
Traditional Knowledge
Some countries have already decided that the existing intellectual property system is not, on its own, adequate to protect traditional knowledge. A number of these have enacted or are in the process of enacting sui generis systems of protection.[233]
The Philippines has enacted legislation, and is considering further provisions,[234] giving indigenous communities rights over their traditional knowledge. These rights extend to controlling access to ancestral lands, access to biological and genetic resources and to indigenous knowledge related to these resources. Access by other parties will be based on the prior informed consent (PIC) of the community obtained in accordance with customary laws. Any benefits arising from genetic resources or associated knowledge will be equitably shared. The legislation however seeks to maintain the free exchange of biodiversity among local communities. The law also seeks to ensure that indigenous communities are able to participate at all levels of decision-making.
Whilst the primary objectives of these pieces of legislation is to recognise, protect and promote the rights of communities and indigenous people including those relating to biological resources and associated traditional knowledge, they also recognise the potential for exploiting these resources. However, Guatemalan law also seeks to preserve and promote the wider use of its traditional knowledge by placing expressions of national culture, including, for example, medicinal knowledge and music, under the protection of the state.[235] Such expressions cannot under the law be sold or be subject of any remuneration. Thus, different types of models are being developed at the national level, seeking to adapt legislation and practice to local needs.
A particularly important question is the extent to which any form of protection recognises the customary laws under which the knowledge evolved. Countries such as Bangladesh, and organisations such as the OAU,[236] are considering sui generis legislation that provides community based rights over biological resources and associated traditional knowledge and are seeking to give increased recognition to the cultural and customary practices of communities. The sui generis system of protection in the Philippines also takes account of customary laws.
The Australian Federal Court has considered the relevance of customary Aboriginal laws and practices in a case of copyright infringement. Although the Court found that it was not able to “recognise the infringement of ownership rights of the kind which reside under Aboriginal law in the traditional owners of the dreaming stories and the imagery such as that used in the artworks of the present applicants,” it did take into account the harm suffered by the aboriginal artists in their cultural environment when considering damages.[237] Whilst such decisions give some degree of recognition to customary laws, they obviously do not go as far as some would like. In our consultations on this subject several people called for greater recognition of customary laws.[238]
Recognition of customary laws, whether they are specifically related to traditional knowledge or not, however raises issues beyond the scope of this report. We believe nevertheless that customary laws relating to traditional knowledge should be respected and, if possible, recognised more widely. Further work to meet these objectives, as for example recently mandated by the 6th Conference of the Parties of the CBD, should be supported.[239]
Whether these national systems as they
evolve will have sufficient common characteristics to enable the development of
an international sui generis system
remains to be seen. We recognise that
there is continuing pressure for the establishment of an international sui generis system, as recently
articulated by the G15 Group of developing countries.[240]
With
such a wide range of material to protect and such diverse reasons for
“protecting it”, it may be that a single all-encompassing sui generis system of protection for traditional knowledge may be
too specific and not flexible enough to accommodate local needs.
As we have discussed already, the ability
to protect, promote and exploit traditional knowledge does not necessarily
depend on the presence of IP rights.
Bringing together, for example, local innovators and entrepreneurs may
be much more relevant. Whatever
measures are put in place or whatever tools are utilised, exploitation is likely to raise the profile of traditional
knowledge and local innovation within communities and encourage greater
involvement by younger members of the community. This is especially likely to happen if tangible economic returns
are generated. However it is important
to remember that not all holders of traditional knowledge would want to see
their knowledge exploited in this way.
A participant in one of our expert workshops, a Kechuan Indian from
Peru, made this point to the Commission.
For many local communities, he explained, the concept of wealth is
completely different to that found in the western world. For such communities, the imperative is to
be able to ensure that their traditional knowledge and the customary laws
governing it are preserved and respected, rather than to obtain monetary
compensation. He also noted that there
was already probably an unrealistic expectation
among traditional knowledge holders of the possible economic value of their
knowledge. Such expectations are of
course raised as a result of high profile cases such as the Hoodia example (Box
4.2).
Misappropriation
of Traditional Knowledge
The nature of traditional knowledge is such that more of it is transmitted orally than written down. This poses particular problems when parties not authorised by the holder of that knowledge seek to obtain IPRs over it. In the absence of any accessible written record, a patent examiner in another country is unable to access documentation that would challenge the novelty or inventiveness of an application based on traditional knowledge. The only option for an aggrieved party, be it the holders of the knowledge, or someone representing them, is to challenge the patent during the granting process or after grant, where national laws permit. For instance, this is what the Indian Government achieved by overturning the patents on basmati (see Box 4.5 below) and turmeric in the US.
The presence of administrative or quasi-judicial patent opposition or re-examination procedures has facilitated the overturning of these patents. In the absence of such procedures it would have been necessary to instigate proceedings before the relevant court with the inherent cost and time implications. Even with such procedures, it is extremely difficult and costly for developing countries to monitor and challenge IPRs issued all around the world. We suggest later in this chapter a possible way of assisting countries to monitor patents granted on inventions consisting of, or developed from, acquired biological material and associated knowledge.
Patent applications claiming traditional knowledge already in the public domain should not be granted. The problem is that the knowledge tends not to be documented, or if it is, it is unlikely to be easily accessible to a patent examiner. In particular, information on traditional knowledge is not likely to be found in the type of patent-based information that patent offices rely most on when assessing novelty and inventiveness. To address this problem, WIPO and a number of developing countries led by India and China are seeking to develop traditional knowledge digital libraries (see Box 4.3). These digital libraries will not only detail in writing considerable amounts of traditional knowledge already in the public domain, but will do so taking into account international classification standards (the WIPO International Patent Classification (IPC) system) so that the data will be easily accessible to patent examiners.
Box 4.3 Traditional Knowledge Digital Library (TKDL) –
An Indian View
In 1999, following the ultimately successful, but
expensive, Indian challenge of the turmeric and basmati patents granted by
USPTO, it was agreed that the Indian National Institute of Science
Communication (NISCOM) and the Department of Indian System of Medicine and
Homoeopathy (ISM&H) would collaborate to establish a Traditional Knowledge
Digital Library (TKDL).
The TKDL project is initially targeting Ayurveda (a
traditional Indian system of medicine), and proposes to document the knowledge
available in public domain (the existing Ayurveda literature) in digitised
format. Information from about 35,000
Slokas (Versus & Prose) and formulations will be inputted on a database,
and it is expected that the web site will have approximately 140,000 Ayurveda
pages. The data will be made available in several international languages
(English, Spanish, German, French, Japanese and Hindi).
The Traditional Knowledge Resource Classification
(TKRC) is an innovative, structured classification system that has been
designed to facilitate the systematic arrangement, dissemination and retrieval
of the information in the traditional knowledge DL. The TKRC is based on the International Patent Classification
system (IPC), with the information classified under section, class, subclass,
group and subgroup for the convenience of its use by the international patent
examiners. But it provides greater
definition of traditional knowledge information by expanding one IPC group
(i.e. AK61K35/78 related to medicinal plants) into about 5000 subgroups.
The TKDL will give legitimacy to existing traditional
knowledge, and by ensuring ease of retrieval of traditional knowledge-related
information by patent examiners will hopefully prevent the granting of patents,
such as the turmeric and neem cases discussed above which claim subject matter
already in the public domain.
Work on such libraries is also being pursued in WIPO
where a specialized Task Force including representatives from China, India, the
USPTO, and the EPO are examining how such libraries can be integrated into the
existing search tools used by patent offices.
WIPO is also examining the extent to which information on traditional knowledge is already available on the Internet. Initial findings from WIPO indicate that the amount of traditional knowledge related information available is substantial and growing. However, much of it is not in a form that would make it either searchable or useable by patent examiners.[241]
The greater documentation of traditional knowledge may not only be of value in preventing the granting of unwarranted patents but also, more importantly, it may contribute to the preservation, promotion and possible exploitation of traditional knowledge. In this respect it is crucial that the documentation process does not prejudice possible IPRs in the material being documented. India’s National Innovation Foundation provides an example of an attempt to address these issues.[242] One of the concerns raised by both WIPO, and a number of developing countries, about many of the databases unearthed by WIPO was whether the information had been recorded with the prior informed consent of the holders of the knowledge. During discussions in WIPO on the documentation of traditional knowledge,[243] differences were also evident among developing countries as to the type of data that could or should be included in any databases. Some countries, for example, argued that such databases are appropriate only for information that was already publicly available in a codified form. Others indicated that traditional knowledge that had not yet been codified could also be included.
Digital libraries of traditional knowledge should, as soon as it is practical, be incorporated into the minimum search documentation lists of patent offices therefore ensuring that the data contained within them will be considered during the processing of patent applications. Holders of the traditional knowledge should play a crucial role in deciding whether such knowledge is included in any databases and should also benefit from any commercial exploitation of the information.
Traditional medicine is perhaps an area that has the potential to be quite well documented. In Lao People’s Democratic Republic, for example, the Government established the Traditional Medicines Resource Centre (TRMC) which is working with local healers to document details of all traditional medicines with a view to promoting a sharing of practices within Laos. The TRMC is also collaborating with the International Co-operative Biodiversity Group (ICBG) in efforts to discover prospective medicinal products. Any benefits, profits or royalties realised from plants and knowledge recovered during the collaboration will be shared with all the communities involved.[244]
IPRs clearly may have a role in exploiting products based on traditional medicine. But the primary objective must be to promote the application of this knowledge to improve human health, rather than to generate income. Indeed it would be unfortunate if the objective of benefit sharing based on commercialisation resulted only in a few people getting richer at the price of restricting access to medicines needed particularly by the poor. The WHO Traditional Medicine Strategy for 2002-2005 clearly bring outs the public health objective.[245] Lessons learnt from this exercise and other similar initiatives should be freely shared and technical assistance provided to assist other countries managing initiatives relating to documentation.
It must however be recognised that much traditional knowledge will continue to be undocumented. The concept of absolute novelty whereby any disclosure including through use, anywhere in the world, is sufficient to destroy the novelty of an invention therefore remains a necessary safeguard. Without this safeguard, patents could continue to be granted for traditional knowledge that is already in the public domain, albeit not through written disclosure. Some countries do not include use outside their country as “prior art.”
Those countries that only include domestic use in their definition of prior art, should give equal treatment to users of knowledge in other countries. In addition, account should be taken of the unwritten nature of much traditional knowledge in any attempts to develop further the patent system internationally.
For some communities the granting of IPRs such as patents over their knowledge can cause great offence. Although provisions exist in most countries to prevent the granting of IPRs on moral grounds, it is questionable whether intellectual property offices will be able to apply them in respect of small indigenous communities. For example, moral grounds for rejecting trademark applications have existed for some time in New Zealand but it has now been considered necessary to define more clearly the scope of this provision. The amendment under consideration would prevent the registration of a trademark where, on reasonable grounds, the use or registration of the mark is likely to offend a significant section of the community, including the Maori.[246] Such measures as this, together with the greater use of searchable databases of traditional knowledge already in the public domain should go some way to preventing the issuing of IP rights on material that is not novel, obvious or likely to cause offence.
However, as we have noted, there is a second group of patents and indeed other IPRs that cause concern. These are rights which essentially meet the usual criteria for patentability or protection but which nevertheless:
· are based on, or consist of, material obtained illegally or without the consent of the holder of the material
· do not fully recognise the contribution made by others to the invention either in terms of ownership of the rights, or in the sharing of any benefits accruing from the commercialisation of the patented invention.
These concerns do not apply just to patents relating to traditional knowledge although, in light of the CBD, the most contentious patents in this area are likely to be those relating to biological resources and/or traditional knowledge associated with such resources. In the Hoodia case, the concern was essentially not about whether the patents should have been granted, but about whether the San would receive a fair share of the benefits of commercialisation. We address possible ways of providing a more equitable balance in such cases below.
As we have seen, one of the main issues in the debate on traditional knowledge is the relationship between intellectual property protection and the ownership and rights pertaining to the knowledge on which the intellectual property right has been based. The context of our discussion of this issue is to consider also how to promote the objectives related to benefit sharing and prior informed consent set out in the CBD. Since the international community, albeit with some important exceptions, has ratified both TRIPS and the CBD there is an obligation to ensure that they reinforce, rather than contradict one another
The Convention, which was agreed in 1992, seeks to promote the conservation of biodiversity and the equitable sharing of benefits arising out of the utilisation of genetic resources.[247] It asserts the sovereign rights of nations over their national resources, and their right to determine access according to national legislation with the aim of facilitating the sustainable use of these resources, promoting access and their common use. It notes that access to genetic resources should be on the basis of prior informed consent, and on mutually agreed terms that provide fair and equitable sharing of the results of R&D and the benefits of commercialisation and utilisation.[248] It also calls for the fair and equitable sharing of the benefits derived from the use of traditional knowledge.[249]
In respect of intellectual property, the CBD states that access and transfer (of genetic resources) should be consistent with the “adequate and effective protection of intellectual property rights.” Governments should put in place policies to ensure that, particularly for developing countries, access to genetic resources takes place on mutually agreed terms. It notes that patents and other IPRs may have an influence on implementation of the Convention, and governments should co-operate (subject to national and international law) in order to ensure that such rights are supportive of and do not run counter to the CBD’s objectives.[250]
The Governing Body of the CBD has now agreed guidelines on access and benefit sharing as a guide to countries when drafting national legislation.[251] But countries face difficult decisions, both practical and conceptual, in putting benefit sharing into practice. First, the resources in question are often not “owned” by anyone in particular, but are the heritage of one or more communities, which are not necessarily cohesive, or all living in one country. Secondly, while some genetic resources can be traced to very specific areas and habitats, in other cases they comprise components from many countries, in which case benefit-sharing arrangements will be totally impractical. Thirdly, because of the diversity of national circumstances or indeed those within nations in relation, for example, to their cultural, economic or institutional conditions, it is very difficult to devise legislation and practices which cover that diversity in ways that facilitate implementation of such measures. Indeed, care will be necessary to ensure that legislation and practices that seek to give effect to the CBD do not in fact unnecessarily restrict or discourage the legitimate use of genetic resources, whether with a view to commercialisation or in terms of scientific research. There is some evidence that the tightening of restrictions in some countries has hindered the access of biologists studying genetic resources.[252]
While recognising these difficulties, our focus is on how intellectual property rules might need to be modified in both developed and developing countries, to provide support for access and benefit sharing. Many argue that since TRIPS says nothing about the CBD, nor the CBD about TRIPS, there can be no conflict between the two agreements. Moreover it is argued, TRIPS supports the CBD in that patenting often engenders commercialisation which generates the benefits that are a prerequisite to any benefit sharing arrangement. Others have countered this argument by pointing out that since patenting based on the use of genetic resources is allowed under TRIPS, (subject to meeting patentability criteria), this does not support the objectives of the CBD because the criteria for patentability do not include prior informed consent or mutually agreed terms for benefit sharing. While the CBD asserts national sovereignty over genetic resources, there is nothing in TRIPS to provide support to these CBD objectives. Foreign companies may obtain private rights derived from national resources, but TRIPS is silent on obligations set out by the CBD.
Nevertheless, even those, mainly from industry, who argue there is no conflict between the CBD and TRIPS, broadly support the underlying principles of the CBD. In particular, since the CBD asserts the principle that nations have sovereignty over their natural resources, those industries that are interested in making use of genetic resources need to ensure that prospecting activities take place on the basis of prior informed consent, and agreements on benefit sharing. If they ignore these principles, then any access to these resources may not be legitimate.
Given the understandable difficulties faced by developing countries in formulating and enforcing laws on access and benefit sharing, we take the view that developed and developing countries should do more to ensure their IP systems help to promote the objectives of the CBD, and to promote the underlying mutuality of interest that should exist between the providers of genetic resources, mainly in developing countries, and the users who are mainly based in developed countries.
One suggestion is that applicants for IP rights which consist of, or are developed from, genetic resources should identify the source of these resources and provide proof that they were acquired with the prior informed consent of the country from which they were taken. Examples of countries who have introduced such requirements into their law are given in Box 4.4.
The territorial nature of patents means that the requirements referred to above apply only in respect of patents issued in those particular countries or regions. For example, they do not have any bearing on patents issued in the US or Japan. This, it is argued, justifies a more international solution to this issue.
A requirement in all patent laws for the patent applicant to disclose the source of origin of the genetic resources and evidence of prior informed consent would it is argued increase transparency and, simply by providing information, assist in the enforcement of any access and benefit sharing agreements. It might also bring to light cases similar to the Hoodia example.
India: Section 10 (contents of specification) of the Patents
Act 1970 as amended by the Patents Second Amendment Act (2002) provides that
the applicant must disclose the source and geographical origin of any biological
material deposited in lieu of a description. Also Section 25 (opposition to
grant of patent) as amended allows for opposition to be filed on the ground
that “the complete specification does not disclose or wrongly mentions the
source or geographical origin of biological material used for the
invention".
Andean Communities: Andean Decision 486 provides in Article 26 that
applications for patents shall be filed with the competent national office and
shall contain:
h) a copy of the contract for access, if the products
or processes for which a patent application is being filed were obtained or
developed from genetic resources or by products originating in one of the
Member Countries;
i) if applicable, a copy of the document that
certifies the licence or authorization to use the traditional knowledge of
indigenous, African American, or local communities in the Member Countries
where the products or processes whose protection is being requested were
obtained or developed on the basis of the knowledge originating in any one of
the Member Countries, pursuant to the provisions of Decision 391 and its
effective amendments and regulations;
Costa Rica: Biodiversity Law 7788 Article 80 (Obliged prior
consultation) states that “Both the National Seed Office and the Registers of
Intellectual and Industrial Property are obliged to consult with the Technical
Office of the Commission (for the Management of Biodiversity) before granting
protection of intellectual or industrial property to innovations involving
components of biodiversity. They must always provide the certificate of origin
issued by the Technical Office of the Commission and the prior informed
consent. Justified opposition from the Technical Office will prohibit
registration of a patent or protection of the innovation.”
Failure to provide the
necessary information in any of the cases referred to above could lead to the
failure of the application or revocation of the patent.
Europe:
Recital 27 of Directive 98/44 on the legal protection of
biotechnological inventions provides that the patent application should where
appropriate, include information on the geographical origin of biological
material if known. But this is entirely
voluntary, as it is without prejudice to the processing of patent applications or
the validity of rights arising from granted patents.
Opponents argue that seeking to counter illegal access or unauthorised use through patent law does not address instances where patenting is not involved. Moreover, introducing such a requirement only in respect of genetic resources and associated knowledge would discriminate against other cases where patents may have been obtained as the result of illegal or unauthorised activities. It is also argued that this would lead to more legal uncertainty and create “serious difficulties in practice” since it is “often not clear where a biological sample originated.”[253] Even if the immediate source of material is known, this may not be the original source, especially where material is obtained, as is very common, from ex situ collections that have been built up over many years.
It is difficult to judge how real any such uncertainty would be. Where a company is interested in a particular genetic resource it seems likely that it would endeavour to discover as much information about that material as possible because of its relevance to its possible utility (for example, how local populations use it). In such cases it is likely that the geographical origin of the resource will be known. In other cases it may be more difficult to establish the precise geographical origin of an individual sample. Nevertheless it seems unlikely, especially for samples obtained after 1992, that some information on the geographical source of a particular sample is not available. Under the terms of the CBD any benefits are to be shared with the country providing the resource irrespective of whether the resource actually originated in that country.[254] The ITPGR, as we have seen, provides a different mechanism for plant genetic resources of diverse origin.
One of the stated
objectives for requiring disclosure of source of origin and prior informed
consent is to encourage compliance with the access and benefit sharing
principles of the CBD. Other
mechanisms and incentives however exist which may address this objective. Failure to obtain authorisation to access or
use material may, for example, lead to court action under the doctrine of
misappropriation or breach of contract.
But seeking recompense in this way is time-consuming and costly, and of
limited use for many holders of traditional knowledge. In addition, the stigma of being identified
as “a bio-pirate” may also be an incentive for organisations to ensure the
probity of their activities. Known
violators of the CBD may be denied future access to material. Such a sanction has already been considered
in Bangladesh.[255] Suppliers of material may collectively agree
to supply only to organisations prepared to disclose in any patent applications
that they might file full details of any access contracts. It is possible that these incentives alone
may be sufficient. Companies and organisations that use or supply biological material
or traditional knowledge have already adopted or are considering adopting codes
of conduct covering CBD-related activities.[256]
Nevertheless, we believe that it is important to recognise the force of the CBD, even if only a few countries have implemented specific access and benefit sharing legislation. We conclude therefore that where a country has established a clear legal framework governing access to biological material and/or traditional knowledge then that country should be able to take action where IPRs are granted over material or knowledge which was acquired illegally from that country.
Indeed we would go further in supporting the objectives of the CBD by arguing that no person should be able to benefit from any IP rights consisting of or based on genetic resources or associated knowledge obtained in an illegal manner or used in an unauthorised way. Those organisations currently considering this issue should examine what measures may be possible within the existing international framework to meet this objective. As well as the possibility of refusing applications or invalidating rights, we would suggest that consideration also be given to declaring such IPRs unenforceable.[257] Such a sanction is already available in the US under the doctrines of “unclean hands” and inequitable conduct whereby a court will refuse to enforce a patent until the patentee has cleaned his hands or remedied any inequitable conduct or fraud. In interpreting these doctrines the courts have indicated the paramount interest is to ensure that patents issue from “backgrounds free from fraud or other inequitable conduct”.[258] The US Supreme Court has noted also that
“A court of equity acts only when and as conscience
commands; and if the conduct of the plaintiff be offensive to the dictates of
natural justice, then, whatever may be the rights he possesses, and whatever
use he may make of them in a court of law, he will be held remediless in a
court of equity”.[259]
The
principle of equity dictates that a person should not be able to benefit from
an IP right based on genetic resources or associated knowledge acquired in
contravention of any legislation governing access to that material. In such cases the burden should generally
lie with the complainant to prove that the IP holder has acted improperly. However, a precursor for any action is
knowledge of the wrong. It is to assist
in this respect that we believe that a disclosure requirement of the type
discussed above is necessary.
All countries should provide in their
legislation for the obligatory disclosure of information in the patent
application of the geographical source of genetic resources from which the
invention is derived. This requirement should be subject to reasonable
exceptions as, for example, where it is genuinely impossible to identify the
geographical source of material.
Sanctions, possibly of the type discussed above, should be applied only
where it can be shown that the patentee has failed to disclose the known source
or where he has sought to deliberately mislead about the source. This issue should be considered by the
Council for TRIPS, in the context of paragraph 19 of the Doha Ministerial
Declaration.
Consideration should also be given to establishing a system whereby patent offices examining patent applications which identify the geographical source of genetic resources or traditional knowledge pass on that information, either to the country concerned, or to WIPO which may act as a depository for patent-related information on alleged “biopiracy.” Through these measures it will be possible to monitor more closely the use and misuse of genetic resources
GEOGRAPHICAL INDICATIONS
Background
At the beginning of this chapter we consider the relevance of geographical indications for protecting traditional knowledge. However, geographical indications have a much wider application and for some countries constitute one of the most important categories of intellectual property. This is reflected in the TRIPS Agreement.
The negotiations on the geographical indication section of the TRIPS Agreement were among the most difficult.[260] This stemmed from clear divisions between the main proponents of the TRIPS Agreement – the US and EU. In addition, as has been borne out in the subsequent discussions in the TRIPS Council, divisions also exist among other developed countries and among developing countries. The final text of the agreement reflects these divisions and, in mandating further work, recognises that agreement could not be reached in a number of important areas.
The outcome was that the current text of TRIPS provides a basic standard of protection, and a higher standard specifically for wines and spirits. The inclusion of this higher standard does not refer to the unique characteristics of wines and spirits, but was rather a compromise reached in negotiations. This imbalance in protection has led to demands for additional protection from a number of countries including India, Pakistan, Kenya, Mauritius and Sri Lanka.[261] Other countries, such as Argentina, Chile, and Guatemala argue that extending the additional protection to other products would impose extra financial and administrative burdens on all WTO Members and that these would outweigh any trade benefit. They believe that such burdens would fall most heavily on developing countries.
In the absence of a reliable economic assessment, it is difficult to evaluate the merits in both sets of arguments. They also, of course, reflect differences in perceived economic interest between both developed and developing countries. A few countries, for example Egypt and Paraguay, have already indicated that the additional protection for geographical indications for wines and spirits will be made available under their national laws for other products.[262] It will be interesting to see whether providing such comprehensive additional protection leads to significant additional costs or benefits, in the absence of international recognition.
As well as providing increased protection for geographical indications on wines and spirits, TRIPS also requires negotiations to be undertaken in the TRIPS Council concerning the establishment of a multilateral register of geographical indications for wines. The doha Ministerial Conference extended this mandate to negotiate the establishment of a system that includes spirits. The purpose of the register has not been clearly defined. As noted below, groups of countries differ in their views. Some wish to use it as a full international register that would oblige all member countries to provide protection to geographical indications meeting the requirements for registration. Others want it as a voluntary system of registration and source of information.
To date, three different proposals for a multilateral register have been presented. The EU envisages a register that has an effect on all WTO Members irrespective of whether or not they have any geographical indications included on the register.[263] Any WTO Member wishing to challenge the inclusion of a geographical indication in the register is required to notify the country concerned and enter into negotiations with a view to resolving the disagreement. The Hungarian proposal provides that where one WTO Member has successfully challenged the inclusion of a geographical indication on certain specified grounds, then that geographical indication will not need to be protected by other WTO Members.[264] In both of these proposals, inclusion of a geographical indication in the register would constitute a presumption of eligibility for protection under any legal means provided for protecting geographical indications in any WTO Member.
By contrast, the joint proposal from the US, Canada, Chile and Japan provides a system of registration that is binding only on those seeking to participate in the system.[265] Participating members would make use of the register when, for example, examining trademark applications containing or consisting of a geographical indication. Non-participating WTO Members would be encouraged to make similar use of the register. Negotiations on the register are, according to the recent Doha WTO Ministerial Conference, to be completed by the next Conference in Mexico in 2003.
The TRIPS Council Secretariat has already begun to shed some light on how a number of WTO Members, including some developing countries have met their obligations under TRIPS.[266] The vast majority of countries from which information has been obtained provide specific legislation covering geographical indications although it is unclear whether this legislation stems directly from the TRIPS Agreement or was already in place to meet, for example, bilateral commitments.
The administrative burden in giving effect to new legislation for those countries without current protection would not appear that great. This is because TRIPS does not currently require any formal national registration system for geographical indications, and the burden and costs of compelling enforcement therefore falls on the holders of the geographical indication, not the government. As mentioned below, however, the costs of ensuring compliance with quality standards and promoting and enforcing geographical indications abroad may be significant.
In
considering positions to take on the discussions on both the multilateral
register and the possible extension of the scope of protection, it is important
that developing countries consider carefully the potential costs and
benefits. Indeed as we have suggested
elsewhere, we believe that comprehensive economic impact assessments need to be
undertaken before any new IP-related obligations are introduced for developing
countries.
The economic consequences for a developing country are difficult to assess. The main economic benefit of geographical indications would be to act as a quality mark which will play a part in enhancing export markets and revenues. But increased protection, particularly applied internationally, may adversely affect local enterprises which currently exploit geographical indications that may become protected by another party. Thus there will be losses to countries producing substitutes for goods that become protected by geographical indications. A proliferation of geographical indications would tend to reduce their individual value.
It has also been suggested that geographical indications may be of particular interest to a number of developing countries who might have, or might be able to achieve, a comparative advantage in agricultural products and processed foods and beverages.[267] For these countries, seeking and enforcing protection for geographical indications abroad may have economic gains. However the costs involved in such actions, especially enforcement, might be prohibitively high. In addition, prior to seeking protection abroad, it is necessary both to develop and protect the geographical indication in the country of origin. Resources may need to be deployed to ensure that the required quality, reputation or other characteristics of the product covered by the geographical indication are developed and maintained. Effort will also be needed to ensure that the geographical indication does not become an accepted generic term, freely useable by all (see Box 4.5).
In our view it is far from clear whether these countries will be able to gain significantly from the application of geographical indications. By way of example, the Lisbon Agreement, which is an international system of protection administered by WIPO for the protection of appellations of origin, was agreed in 1958.[268] To date only 20 countries (seven of which are developed) have acceded to the agreement, and as of 1998, 766 appellations of origin are protected under the agreement, of which European countries hold 95%.
Basmati is a variety of rice from the Punjab provinces
of India and Pakistan. The rice is a slender, aromatic long grain variety that
originated in this region and is a major export crop for both countries.
Annual basmati exports are worth about $300m, and represent the livelihood of
thousands of farmers.
The ‘Battle for Basmati’ started in 1997 when US Rice
breeding firm RiceTec Inc. was awarded a patent (US5663484) relating to plants
and seeds, seeking a monopoly over various rice lines including some having
characteristics similar to Basmati lines. Concerned about the potential effect
on exports, India requested a re-examination of this patent in 2000. The
patentee in response to this request withdrew a number of claims including
those covering basmati type lines. Further claims were also withdrawn following
concerns raised by the USPTO. The dispute has however moved on from the patent
to the misuse of the name ‘Basmati’.
In some countries the term ‘Basmati’ can be applied
only to the long grain aromatic rice grown in India and Pakistan. RiceTec also
applied for registration of the trademark ‘Texmati’ in the UK claiming that
‘Basmati’ was a generic term. It was successfully opposed, and the UK has
established a code of practice for marketing rice. Saudi Arabia (the world’s
largest importer of Basmati rice) has similar regulations on the labelling of
Basmati rice.
The code states that “the belief in consumer, trade
and scientific circles [is] that the distinctiveness of authentic Basmati rice
can only be obtained from the northern regions of India and Pakistan due to the
unique and complex combination of environment, soil, climate, agricultural
practices and the genetics of the Basmati varieties”.
But in 1998 the US Rice Federation submitted
that the term ‘Basmati’ is generic and refers to a type of aromatic rice. In
response, a collective of US and Indian civil society organizations filed a
petition seeking to prevent US-grown rice from being advertised with the word
‘Basmati’. The US Department of
Agriculture and the US Federal Trade Commission rejected it in May 2001.
Neither considered the labeling of rice as ‘American-grown Basmati’ misleading,
and deemed ‘Basmati’ a generic term.
The problem is not just limited to the US; Australia,
Egypt, Thailand and France also grow basmati type rice and may take the lead
from the US and officially deem ‘basmati’ a generic term.
The name "Basmati" (and the Indian and
Pakistani export markets) can be protected by registering it as a Geographical
Indication. However, India and Pakistan will have to explain why they did not
take action against the gradual adoption of generic status of basmati over the
last 20 years. For example, India did not lodge a formal protest when the US
Federal Trade Commission formally declared ‘basmati’ generic.
Even taking into account the well documented weaknesses in the Lisbon Agreement, such as the lack of an appropriate exception for geographical indications that had become generic, that make it unattractive to both developed and developing countries alike, the level of interest, even for those developing countries who deemed it worthwhile to join, seems very limited.[269]
Within the framework of the discussions in the WTO on a multilateral register, it has been proposed that more consideration should be given, inter alia, to the likely cost of introducing the type of register proposed by the EU.[270] A similar call for this type of analysis was made by a number of developing countries during recent discussions in WIPO.[271] However the necessary support to take it forward was not forthcoming from some of the same countries now pressing for such work in the WTO. We, like others, believe only with this type of analysis will developing countries, particularly low income ones, be able to take informed positions on the continuing debates on geographical indications, especially within the WTO.[272]
Further
research should be undertaken, as a matter of urgency, by a competent body,
possibly UNCTAD, to assess in respect of developing countries:
·
the actual or likely costs of implementing existing geographical
indications provisions under TRIPS
·
what role geographical indications could play in the
development of these countries
·
the likely costs and benefits of extending the current additional
protection for wines and spirits to other products
·
the costs and benefits of the various proposals put forward for
establishing a multilateral register of geographical indications.
Chapter
5
INTRODUCTION
Any serious enquiry into the subject of IP and development has to consider the crucially important role of copyright and the copyright-based industries (including publishing, film, television, radio, music and now computer software too) in the production and dissemination of knowledge and knowledge-based products. These industries supply the intellectual “raw material” for science and innovation, as well as for education and instruction in general, and they have helped bring about dramatic increases in productivity through aiding the creation of information-based products like desk-top publishing software, electronic mail or sophisticated scientific computer databases. Moreover, the copyright-based industries have developed into a huge source of wealth and employment creation in the knowledge-based global economy. In the US, for example, their overall combined value has increased at such a rapid rate in the last twenty or thirty years, that together they currently contribute more than $460 billion to US gross domestic product and sold almost $80 billion in exports in 1999.[273]
For developing countries this provides both enormous opportunities and challenges:
“The creation and ownership of
knowledge products are of increasing importance because of the centrality of
information and knowledge to post-industrial economies. The concept of
copyright, originally intended to protect authors and publishers of books, has
broadened to include other knowledge products such as computer programs and
films… Copyright has emerged as one of the most important means of regulating
the international flow of ideas and knowledge-based products, and will be a
central instrument for the knowledge industries of the twenty-first century.
Those who control copyright have a significant advantage in the emerging, knowledge-based
global economy. The fact is that copyright ownership is largely in the hands of
the major industrialized nations and of the major multimedia corporations
placing low per capita income countries as well as smaller economies at a
significant disadvantage.”[274]
The legal protection of copyright dates back to the 1700s with the Statute of Anne, and at the end of the 19th century it was enshrined in the Berne Convention. Although the language of the Convention suggests a paradigm for the protection of the rights of authors and artists, in many cases copyright belongs not to individuals but to the firms that employ them. Indeed, copyright is an essential element in the business model of publishers, television and record companies, and software producers because they grant their owners exclusive rights, inter alia, over the reproduction and distribution of protected works. The new information and communication technologies (ICTs), and in particular the Internet enable unauthorised creation of unlimited, perfect and costless copies of protected works, as well as their almost instantaneous and worldwide distribution. This poses an unprecedented challenge to copyright law. Some believe the future will see copyright become of far less importance as industries switch to technology-based protection, in the form of encryption and anti-circumvention measures, supplemented by contract law and sui generis forms of IP protection for databases.
We believe that copyright-related issues have become increasingly relevant and important for developing countries as they enter the information age and struggle to participate in the knowledge-based global economy. Of course, some developing countries have long standing concerns that copyright protection for books and learning materials, for example, may make it harder for them to achieve their goals in education and research. These were prominently expressed at the 1967 Stockholm Conference of the Berne Convention and remain valid today.
Copyright deserves special attention now not only because millions of poor people still lack access to books and other copyrighted works, but because the last decade has seen rapid advances in information and communication technologies, transforming the production, dissemination and storage of information. This has been accompanied by a strengthening of national and international copyright protection. Indeed, it was largely these technological changes that led the copyright-based industries in the developed countries to lobby for TRIPS and the WIPO Copyright Treaty, as well as the sui generis protection system for databases established by the EU in 1996. These trends are likely to have both positive and negative aspects for developing nations and it is important to understand how they impact on such countries, particularly the poor.
The crucial issue for developing countries is getting the right balance between protecting copyright and ensuring adequate access to knowledge and knowledge-based products. It is the issues of the cost of access, and the interpretation of “fair use” or “fair dealing” exemptions that are particularly critical for developing countries, made more so by the extension of copyright to software and to digital material. These issues need to be addressed to ensure developing countries have access to important knowledge-based products as they seek to bring education to all, facilitate research, improve competitiveness, protect their cultural expressions and reduce poverty.
In this chapter we consider the following issues:
· How important is copyright as a stimulus to cultural and other industries in developing countries?
· How does copyright affect developing countries as consumers of products from abroad, particularly educational material, including via the Internet?
· What should developing countries do about enforcement of copyright?
· How does copyright on software affect developing countries?
COPYRIGHT
AS A STIMULUS TO CREATION
As agencies such as WIPO, UNESCO and the World Bank have pointed out, it is important that developing countries develop mechanisms to protect and benefit from the commercial exploitation of their own past and present creative works. On this view, copyright can play an important role in the development of cultural industries in developing countries by ensuring rewards through exclusive rights over copying and distribution.[275] In Chapter 4, we discuss the issues relating to protection of traditional knowledge in developing countries and much of that is also relevant here, in so far as such knowledge and creativity may be protectable under copyright.
From a global perspective, the direct rewards from copyright protection are largely directed to the publishing, entertainment and software industries in Europe and North America. As Figure 5.1 below shows, the US, UK, Germany, Spain, France and Italy between them produced nearly two thirds of global exports of books in 1998. But, in some instances, copyright-based industries in developing countries are also flourishing and obtaining a share of these rewards.
Perhaps the most famous case is the Indian software industry. Between 1994-95 and 2001-02, the industry’s gross earnings expanded from $787 million to $10.2 billion (a large proportion of which were software exports, which grew in value during the period from $489 million to $7.8 billion) and by March 2002, the software and services sector employed about 520,000 workers.[276] And certainly there is a wealth of creative talent in developing countries – such as the musicians in Mali and Jamaica or the traditional artists in Nepal – which could be harnessed to generate more wealth for emerging economies. But this will only happen if there is a local infrastructure for cultural industries, for example for publishing and recording. Currently many writers and musicians in developing countries (particularly in Africa) have to rely on foreign publishers or record companies.
Source:
UNESCO (2000a)
At the same time, whilst there are success stories like India’s software industry, there are also developing countries who have provided copyright protection as members of the Berne Convention for decades (such as Benin or Chad which joined in 1971) and have not seen significant increases in their national copyright-based industries or in the level of copyright-protected works being created by their people.
The evidence suggests, therefore, that the availability of copyright protection may be a necessary but not a sufficient condition for the development of viable domestic industries in the publishing, entertainment and software sectors in developing countries. Many other factors are important for the sustained development of such copyright-based industries in developing countries. Taking the publishing industry in Africa as an example, factors such as the unpredictability of textbook purchasing by governments and donors, weak management skills in local firms, high costs for printing equipment and paper, and poor access to finance are likely to continue to act as very severe constraints in many countries for the foreseeable future.[277]
Moreover, given the small market size of many developing countries, the availability of copyright protection may be most significant from a commercial standpoint in export markets rather than domestically, notwithstanding the fact that authors and companies from developing countries may face insurmountable costs when action to enforce their rights in such markets is required. Of course, in larger developing countries like India, China, Brazil or Egypt, copyright protection in the domestic market is clearly of considerable importance to national publishing, film, and music and software industries. Although, as we have noted, during the 19th century the US sought to aid the development of its domestic publishing industry by not recognising the rights of foreign copyright holders.
In order to realize the potential benefits of copyright, some developing countries have established collective management societies, which represent the rights of artists, authors and performers and collect royalties from licensing copyrighted works held in their inventories. At present, only a minority of developing countries has followed this approach and there are quite different views on the merits of the establishment of collective management societies. WIPO and some donor agencies actively advocate and support them, as do some developing country governments (for example, in the Caribbean). Copyright-based industry groups in developed countries also argue that the establishment of Reprographic Rights Organisations in developing countries would facilitate wider provision of access to protected works through photocopying at rates suited to the local market.
On the other hand, some commentators argue that although such organisations in developing countries may collect royalties for local authors and artists, they are likely to collect far more for foreign rights holders from developed countries who may often dominate the market place for copyrighted works. For example, in South Africa, where the balance is likely to be more favourable than in lower income developing countries, its Dramatic, Artistic and Literary Rights Organisation (DALRO) distributed a total of approximately €74,000 to national rights holders, of which approximately €20,000 were received from foreign collecting societies; whilst over the same period it distributed approximately €137,000 to foreign rights holders.[278] It is also important to recognise that collective management organisations can potentially wield significant market power and may act in an anti-competitive manner. This is particularly of concern in developing countries with weak institutional capacities and regulatory frameworks.
Although the potential benefits from the development of copyright-based industries in some developing countries may be enticing in some cases, it is hard not to conclude from looking at the evidence from the developing world overall that the negative impacts of stronger copyright protection are likely to be more immediate and significant for the majority of the world’s poor. Today, there is an enormous “knowledge gap” between the richest and the poorest countries. As the World Bank has noted:
“If knowledge gaps widen, the world will be split further, not just by disparities in capital and other resources, but by the disparity in knowledge. Increasingly, capital and other resources will flow to those countries with the stronger knowledge bases, reinforcing inequality. There is also the danger of widening knowledge gaps within countries, especially developing ones, where a fortunate few surf the World Wide Web while others remain illiterate. But threat and opportunity are opposite sides of the same coin. If we can narrow knowledge gaps and address information problems … it may be possible to improve incomes and living standards at a much faster pace than previously imagined.”[279]
In the long term, stronger copyright protection may help to stimulate local cultural industries in developing countries if other conditions affecting the success of such industries are also met. But in the short to medium term, it is likely to reduce the ability of developing countries and poor people to close this gap by getting the textbooks, scientific information and computer software they need at affordable cost.
In theory, international copyright rules should be able to deal with problems of access because they provide room for countries to include exemptions and relaxations of copyright in certain circumstances under their national laws. So, for example, Articles 9 and 10 of the Berne Convention permit countries to allow limited copying of protected works without permission for certain purposes defined in national legislation such as teaching, research and private use, so long as these do not interfere with the normal exploitation of the work by the copyright owner (see Box 5.1).
As part of the balance between the exclusive rights of
authors, artists and other creators on the one hand, and the social goal of
wide dissemination of knowledge on the other, international copyright rules
allow countries to place limits on the right to
prevent unauthorised use and reproduction in certain prescribed
circumstances. For example, article 9, paragraph 2 of the Berne Convention
states "It shall be a matter for
legislation in the countries of the Union to permit the reproduction of such
works in certain special cases, provided that such reproduction does not
conflict with a normal exploitation of the work and does not unreasonably
prejudice the legitimate interests of the author".
Accordingly, national copyright laws in most countries
incorporate exceptions for copying for personal use, research, education,
archival copying, library use and news reporting, based on principles of ‘fair
dealing’, or in the US, the doctrine of ‘fair use’. The scope, strength and
flexibility of these exceptions vary widely between countries and regions, in
part due to differing national jurisprudence, but generally focus on the
following conditions:
·
The purpose
and character of the use – copying must be for private, non-commercial
purposes. Only single or a small number of copies may be reproduced.
·
The
proportion of the work that is copied – copies should be made only of parts of
the work. Complete works may be copied only where originals are not available
on the market.
·
Copies of
hard copy works may typically be produced only by reprographic processes. There
is also some freedom to make copies of electronic works as, for example, for
time-shifting of TV programs or archiving of computer software.
·
If there are
exemptions for the benefit of libraries and archives, those institutions must
be accessible to the public and act in a non-commercial way.
·
The
legitimate interest of the right-holder must be taken into account – the effect
on the potential market for the work.
The development and diffusion of
digital technology, however, now permits
unauthorised creation of unlimited, perfect and costless copies, and the almost
instantaneous and worldwide distribution of protected works. The copyright industries are responding by using
digital technology, in the form of encryption technologies and
anti-circumvention measures, supplemented by contract law and sui generis forms of databases
protection. Critics argue that these
measures effectively restrict “fair use”, and may reduce the ability of
teachers, students, researchers and consumers to access information,
particularly in developing countries. On this view, new approaches are needed
to ensure that appropriate “fair use” exceptions can be preserved in this
digital context.[280]
At the 1967
Stockholm conference of the Berne Convention, developing countries argued for
additional flexibilities within international copyright rules because of their
needs for mass education. The conference produced a Protocol that allowed
developing countries to provide a reduced term of protection of 25 years
together with compulsory licensing for translations into local languages and,
most controversially, for any protected use for educational, scientific or
research purposes. But the Stockholm
Protocol was never ratified because of a lack of consensus between developed
and developing countries. Eventually,
in Paris in 1971, agreement was reached on a watered down set of exemptions for
developing countries, essentially allowing limited compulsory licensing of
works for translation into local languages.
These are set out in an Appendix to the Convention, but it has been of
very little direct benefit to developing countries, as shown by the fact that
only a handful of developing countries have ever included the special
provisions in their national law.[281]
A central question is whether the exemptions and limitations within the existing framework of international rules allow developing countries to set the right balance in protecting copyright whilst addressing their special development needs. There are certainly grounds for doubt. As one distinguished international copyright expert has put it:
“Where a developing country decides to enter
international copyright relations it will generally find that a perceptible gap
remains between what is needed to satisfy its requirements [for education and
transfer of knowledge] and the standard of protection demanded by a
multilateral instrument such as the Berne Convention.” [282]
In fact, our consultations with stakeholders and reading of the evidence suggests that the issues are most serious in relation to access to education materials where demand is not met by the local publishing industries or donor-financed programmes; and in relation to access to computer software, a pre-requisite for access to information and for competitiveness in the global economy. The arrival of the digital era provides great opportunities for developing countries in accessing information and knowledge. The development of digital libraries and archives, Internet-based distance learning programmes, and the ability of scientists and researchers to access sophisticated on-line computer databases of technical information in real time are just some examples. But the arrival of the digital era also poses some new and serious threats for access and dissemination of knowledge. In particular, there is a real risk that the potential of the Internet in the developing world will be lost as rights owners use technology to prevent public access through pay-to-view systems.
COPYRIGHT-BASED
INDUSTRIES AND COPYING OF PROTECTED WORKS
As we note at the beginning of this chapter, copyright-based industries such as publishing and computer software play a major part in the global knowledge-based economy, and the products and services they provide have a central role in facilitating innovation and social and economic development in general. The success of these industries is reflected by their tremendous growth, which has generated millions of high-paying jobs and billions in revenues, including in some developing countries. The computer software industry is also a highly important source of innovation in its own right and its members argue that they have produced dramatic gains in the performance and functionality of many commercial software products in the last decade or so while prices have remained stable or even fallen.
Representatives from these industries have stressed to us the importance of copyright laws and strong protection against unauthorised copying to encourage investments in creativity and innovation, as well as in product and technological development. The scale of these investments in developing creative works and bringing them to market is certainly considerable. For example, according to the Publishers’ Association there are around 600,000 books currently in print in UK. This is a hugely valuable knowledge resource for innovative industries and society at large. And of course, industries must be able to recoup these investments to pay for new generations of knowledge-based products. So, for example, the computer software industry argues that charging licence fees for its products allows companies to generate revenues to fund future R&D.
The prevention of unauthorized copying has always been the principal objective behind the development of international copyright rules and this remains the case. Unauthorised copying of copyrighted works (usually described rather more pejoratively as “piracy” by copyright holders) has a long history and remains an international phenomenon, occurring in both the developed and the developing world. The US, for example, justified its persistent refusal to grant copyright protection to foreign authors during the 19th century on the grounds that this was a necessity to meet the nation’s needs for knowledge and enlightenment. And interestingly, although industry claims that current rates of unauthorised copying are highest in some developing countries and transition economies,[283] the biggest financial losses to rights holders still occur in developed countries, because their market size is so much bigger.[284] The arrival of the digital era has created the fear for the copyright-based industries that they may be able to sell “only one copy” of a new e-book, DVD movie, music CD, or computer programme before it is illegally copied, as a perfect replica at no cost, and may be distributed seamlessly worldwide through computer networks and the Internet.
In the past, however, the evidence shows that weak levels of copyright enforcement have had a major impact on diffusion of knowledge and knowledge-based products in certain cases, such as computer software, throughout the developing world. Indeed, it is arguably the case that many poor people in developing countries have only been able to access certain copyrighted works through using unauthorised copies available at a fraction of the price of the genuine original product. We are therefore concerned that an unintended impact of stronger protection and enforcement of international copyright rules as required, inter alia, by TRIPS will be simply to reduce access to knowledge products in developing countries, with damaging consequences for poor people.
Responding to this concern, representatives from the copyright-based industries point to the special initiatives they are undertaking for developing countries, such as donation schemes and low price “budget” editions of books and computer programmes for cost-sensitive users, as the way forward rather than any weakening of international copyright rules and/or enforcement measures in the developing world. For example, the publishing industry is now supporting an expanding number of initiatives aimed at improving affordable access to books and journals in developing countries and establishing partnerships with publishers in less developed countries to encourage the development of local publishing industries.[285] Likewise, in the computer software industry, a leading software company is making several of its software products available to South Africa’s 32,000 public schools at no charge, thereby helping South African students and teachers become IT-proficient, while helping to build its future markets.
But ultimately commercial companies are responsible to their shareholders. They are not charities, nor are they intended to be. Companies therefore think it is the responsibility of governments from developed countries and development agencies to meet developing countries’ requirement for subsidised access to affordable copyrighted works in order to address their needs for education and transfer of knowledge. As noted in a report presented to the UK Parliament in 1977 and by a recent decision of the UK Copyright Tribunal no one has yet suggested that the makers of notebooks, compasses or rulers should supply them to educational establishments free of charge.[286] So why should the copyright-based industries tolerate widespread unauthorised copying of their books, journals, computer software or scientific databases?
We have considered these arguments carefully. We recognise the value of the voluntary initiatives being undertaken by industry for developing countries and think more could be done in this area. More generally, we are not convinced from our observation in different developing countries that, even from the rightsholder’s perspective, the pricing of products is optimal. To the extent that copying, particularly on a commercial scale, is driven by the ratio of the selling price to the cost of producing copies, there must be scope for the use of more differential pricing in developing countries that would either be revenue-neutral or even revenue- enhancing for producing industries. The fact that publishers are prepared to support various schemes for low or no cost access for institutions in developing countries for on-line publications indicates that they recognise there is scope for differential pricing, with suitable safeguards. Whilst we fully accept that copyright holders have a right to appropriate returns from their investments just as other industries, we believe that from the wider public policy perspective, ultimately it is just as important to ensure that people in developing countries have better access to knowledge, as it is to ensure they have access to other essential inputs for development such as food, water and medicines. It is not clear to us that publishers, and software producers, have got the balance right in facilitating access in developing countries in ways that are consistent with their obligations to shareholders.
Publishers, both of hard copy and on-line books and
journals, and software producers should review their pricing policies to help
reduce unauthorised copying and to facilitate access to their products in
developing countries. Initiatives being
undertaken by publishers to expand access to their products for developing
countries are valuable and we encourage an expansion of such schemes. The
extension of free on-line access initiatives for developing countries to cover
all academic journals is a good example of what could be done.
In recent years, there has been a welcome expansion of primary and secondary education in developing countries, and aid has been concentrated rightly in these sectors. Whilst there are still major challenges in achieving “Education for All”, developing countries and their donor partners are making significant progress.[287] Access to books and reading materials at primary and secondary levels in some countries has also improved. This is the result of increased levels of public expenditure on primary educationand international book donation programmes, such as Book Aid International. And importantly, in some countries, it is also because local publishing industries, albeit often at an embryonic stage, are able to produce low cost schoolbooks and reading materials.[288]
However, access to books and learning materials is still a real problem in many developing countries. In 1999, research by the Association for Development of Education in Africa (ADEA), a consortium of donors and developing countries, revealed that shortages of relevant, low cost books for use inside and outside school continue to undermine the provision of good quality education. Indeed, the conclusions of ADEA’s research present a very depressing picture:
“Uneven access to teaching and learning materials,
inadequate provision of reading materials for the development of vital literacy
skills and unacceptable pupil/book ratios continue to predominate. African
publishers continue to be at a disadvantage in an economic context that tends
to favour the import of books from abroad at the expense of those published
in-country.” [289]
But access to books and materials is important for other parts of the education system as well. Developing countries need educated people such as doctors, nurses, lawyers, scientists, researchers, engineers, economists, teachers and accountants. Without people skilled in these professions and a system of life-long learning and education, developing countries will be less able to absorb new technologies, generate innovation, and compete in the global knowledge economy. For example, even if developing countries can obtain cheap medicines they will still need trained doctors and nurses to administer them properly in order to save lives.
However, in many
developing countries, particularly in Sub-Saharan Africa, the tertiary
education sector has sunk to levels where it may soon no longer be able to
provide minimum levels of teaching and research – and this at a time of growing
demand for admissions for undergraduates.[290] With many developing countries already
spending a significant proportion of GNP on education, they may be unable to
find the additional resources required simply to maintain current levels of
tertiary enrolments, let alone improve quality. Clearly, copyright is not the only issue with the weak tertiary
infrastructure but high prices of books and materials and limited access to
Internet-based resources are still important parts of a worsening crisis.
In the tertiary sector, the evidence indicates that access to books and other materials for education and research remains a critical problem in many developing countries, particularly the poorest. Most developing countries remain heavily dependent on imported textbooks and reference books, as this sector is often not commercially feasible for struggling local publishers to enter. The prices of such books are beyond the means of most students.
University libraries should play a key role in supporting research and ensuring access to copyrighted books, journals and on-line materials for poor students in developing countries, but they are typically in a very poor state. Donor agencies have provided funding to modernise and re-stock libraries in a number of countries, including providing Internet connectivity and photocopying facilities.[291] More of this assistance is urgently needed. But donors’ systems are just too slow and bureaucratic to enable libraries to maintain up-to-date textbook collections. Generally, the situation for university libraries in the poorer developing countries remains very bleak[292], particularly in Africa, as a recent UNESCO report noted:
“[T]he
downturn in the economic fortunes of African countries during the last
decade or so has had a devastating effect on the quality of library services in
academic institutions, virtually all of which are publicly funded. Most of them
can no longer afford to buy new books, and large proportions of periodical
subscriptions have been cancelled. With a corresponding inability to switch to
the new information technologies, African university libraries in particular,
and African academics in general, face a dim future indeed.”[293]
Our consultations have also found that for better-resourced university libraries in developing countries, such as South Africa, there are sometimes serious problems in having to obtain copyright clearance and pay royalties for materials needed by teachers and students. And the evidence we have reviewed indicates that even these better-funded libraries have had to reduce their subscriptions to academic journals dramatically due to the high costs of maintaining up to date collections. Indeed, even well resourced libraries in developed countries are experiencing extreme difficulty in continuing to stock the full range of journals their academics and students expect. In developed countries the rapid increase in subscription prices for academic journals, and ongoing consolidation in the publishing industry has fuelled an active debate on how researchers can maintain access to the materials they need, and the development of alternative models of on-line publishing such as BioMed Central.[294]
But developing countries also need to be allowed greater freedom to relax international copyright rules to meet their educational and research needs. As we have noted, delegates at the Stockholm conference proposed a package of such amendments to the Berne Convention in 1967. Developed countries rejected these proposals because they were considered to place too radical limitations on copyright protection. Examining the evidence 30 years later, it is clear to us that the special provisions for developing countries that were added to the Berne Convention in 1971, as set out in the Appendix, have not been effective. Further reforms are therefore needed, and different measures may be more or less important in meeting the specific needs in individual countries. As one commentator has put it:
“In some cases,
access to scientific journals and books at subsidized prices for a limited
period would help greatly. In others, local publishers with limited markets
need easy and inexpensive access to foreign books in order to translate them
into the local language. In a different context, permission to reprint books
from the industrialised countries in the original language is needed to serve
an indigenous population literate in English or French but unable to pay the
high cost of imported books. And for some countries, most of the elements of an
indigenous publishing industry are missing and there is a need to build it up
from scratch. Copyright may not be the key element in all of these
circumstances, but it does play a role.”[295]
In order to improve access to
copyrighted works and achieve their goals for education and knowledge transfer,
developing countries should adopt pro-competitive measures under copyright
laws. Developing countries should be
allowed to maintain or adopt broad exemptions for educational, research and
library uses in their national copyright laws. The implementation of
international copyright standards in the developing world must be undertaken
with a proper appreciation of the continuing high level of need for improving
the availability of these products, and their crucial importance for social and
economic development.
As others have noted, there is a digital divide between the developed countries and the developing world. In the knowledge-based global economy, computer technologies are an essential requirement for accessing and using information, accelerating technology transfer and boosting the growth of productivity. At the same time, computer software products are perhaps the most heavily protected of all forms of knowledge-based products. Under the TRIPS Agreement, computer programmes now qualify for copyright protection just as any other literary work, as well as for other forms of IP protection, including by patents in some nations, such as the US.
Developing countries, of course, have a range of requirements for computer software applications in their industries, hospitals, schools and government offices. But most commonly, they need affordable access to off-the-shelf business software packages, such as word-processing, spreadsheet, e-mail and Internet browsing products. Companies in Europe and North America, with Microsoft being the major player, dominate the global market for these products. The software industries of developing countries, even in India, are mostly absent from the off-the-shelf, packaged computer programs sector.[296]
Copyright matters most in the computer software industry to the off-the-shelf business applications sector. Unlike bespoke software applications, these products have a mass market and can be easily copied. Copyright protection enables companies to prevent copying, limit competition and charge monopoly prices for these products. In developing countries, this presents two main problems.
First, as there is currently widespread copying together with low local purchasing power in developing countries, there is a concern that stronger protection and enforcement could mean a more limited diffusion of such technologies. This may be a particular risk because the network effects of business applications tend to re-enforce the dominance of existing software producers. Examining the evidence, however, we conclude that this problem is not insurmountable for developing countries, if the right steps are taken. For example, governments and donor organisations could review their software procurement policies with a view to giving greater consideration to low cost business software products, including generic and open-source products that are widely available.[297]
The second problem is that where the source code of software is also protected, this may make it harder to adapt the products for local needs. It may also restrain competition in development of inter-operating applications, through follow-on innovation by reverse engineering. Under TRIPS, developing countries are permitted the flexibility to allow reverse engineering of software, so this problem may be avoided if national copyright laws are drafted appropriately. As another practical measure, more widespread use of the various open source software[298] products, where source code is made available unlike propriety software, may be considered.[299] Alternatively, some in industry argue that with stronger copyright enforcement, closed source proprietary developers may be more willing to make source code available to software developers in developing countries.
It is clearly beyond our mandate to recommend what kind of policies developing countries should follow for procurement of computer software. For instance, whilst low cost or open source software may a priori offer cost and other advantages over proprietary software, many factors besides software licence fees affect the total cost of an IT system such as customising the system to the user’s specific needs, as well as servicing, and maintaining the system. That said, given the considerable needs which developing countries have for information and communication technologies and the limited funds which are available, it would seem sensible that governments and donors should certainly consider supporting programmes to raise awareness about low cost options, including open source software, in developing countries.
Developing countries and
their donor partners should review policies for procurement of computer
software, with a view to ensuring that options for using low-cost and/or
open-source software products are properly considered and their costs and
benefits carefully evaluated.
Developing countries should ensure that their national copyright laws
permit the reverse engineering of computer software programmes beyond the
requirements for inter-operability, consistent with the relevant IP treaties
they have joined.
There is reason to hope that the information technology revolution has the potential to increase access to information and knowledge in developing countries. Rapid advances in two key technologies – digital information storage/processing and satellite/optical fibre communications – are creating faster and cheaper ways of accessing and using knowledge around the world. The growth of the Internet is a prime example. In mid-1993, there were fewer than 200 websites on the Internet but by late 2000, there were 20 million; and the number of Internet users is expected to reach 1 billion by 2005, though most of these will still be in the developed countries (UNDP 2001). Table 5.1 shows the dramatic contrasts in Internet usage in developed, developing and least developed countries.
Table 5.1 Internet Connectivity in the Developed and
Developing World in 2000
|
Internet Users (millions) |
Population (millions) |
Internet
Users per 10,000 people |
Developed countries |
253.2 |
860 |
2944 |
Developing countries |
107.0 |
4500 |
238 |
Least Developed Countries |
0.7 |
780 |
9 |
Total |
360.9 |
6140 |
588 |
Source: ITU (2001), as quoted in Story (2002) Appendix 4
The growth of the Internet offers real opportunities for improving access and transfer of knowledge for developing countries. For example, the growing size and number of digital libraries creates unprecedented kinds of access to all published information anywhere in the world. In the future, developing countries may be able to build a national digital network to provide access to library resources from around the world to every remote village, as is being done in Australia.[300] Similarly, initiatives such as the African Virtual University (AVU) are showing the potential of the Internet as a tool and resource for distance learning in the developing world. Since its launch in 1997, more than 24,000 students in 17 African countries have completed semester-long courses in technology, engineering, business and the sciences through the AVU. It also provides students with access to an on-line digital library with over 1,000 full text journals and the AVU website currently receives more than 1 million hits per month.[301]
But there are also threats to access and diffusion of knowledge and technology from these technological changes. There is a growing trend within the publishing and software industries towards distribution of content on-line, together with access restrictions enforced by digital rights management systems, such as encryption technologies. This sophisticated form of technological protection rescinds traditional “fair use” rights to browse, share, or make private copies of copyrighted works in digital formats, since works may not be accessible without payment, even for legitimate uses. For developing countries, where Internet connectivity is limited and subscriptions to on-line resources unaffordable, it may exclude access to these materials altogether and impose a heavy burden that will delay the participation of those countries in the global knowledge-based society.
In terms of the relationship of this trend with IP rules and the potential of the Internet for development, there are three factors that have further significance for developing countries.
First, the WIPO Copyright Treaty establishes new rules that may soon become the international standard.[302] It clarifies copyright holders’ exclusive rights over material in the on-line environment and specifically calls for countries to provide effective legal remedies against the circumvention of technological protection measures restricting types of access that are not authorised by the copyright holder or permitted in national law. As of April 2002, 35 countries had ratified the treaty, including Burkina Faso, Mali and Gabon. An important concern here is that developing countries will come under pressure, for instance in the context of bilateral agreements with developed countries (see Chapter 8), to accede to the WIPO Copyright treaty, or even to adopt stricter prohibitions against circumvention of technological protection systems and effectively thereby reducing the scope of traditional “fair use” in digital media.
In the US, the Digital Millennium Copyright Act (DMCA) of 1998 enacted the WIPO Treaty but went beyond it. In particular it gave a strong boost to the use of technological protection by making it illegal to circumvent technological protection used by publishers, or to develop or distribute devices that do so. Such acts are illegal even for uses that would not hitherto have infringed on copyright (which is not the case with the WIPO treaty). This deeply compromises the principles of “fair use” which have been established under copyright, as also the principle of first sale. In the case of a book you are free to resell it to someone else – technological protection may prevent the equivalent digital act. Finally, technological protection is indefinite, whereas copyright is time limited (albeit the time seems to keep increasing).
Secondly, certain quarters of the “content” industries are calling for governments to enact legislation that require manufacturers of computer technology to build-in devices to prevent unauthorised copying of digital works. For example, Michael Eisner, chairman and chief executive of the Walt Disney company, asserted in a article in the Financial Times on 25 March 2002 that:
“We are now at a crossroads. The primary goal must be
for the creators of content and the creators of computer technology to come
together to agree on appropriate technologies to hinder the unauthorised
duplication and transmission of copyrighted materials. The US government has an
important role to play, by setting a reasonable deadline after which, if no progress
has been made, it will step in to mandate technological standards to protect
copyrighted works from unlawful exploitation.”
Thirdly, specifically in relation to scientific or technical electronic databases, it is possible that developing countries will be encouraged to adopt a special regime of IP protection, in addition to the limited protection already provided under TRIPS and the Berne convention (see Box 5.2). Such a sui generis protection regime was introduced in the 15 countries of the European Union in 1996.[303] Aided by the fact that the EU’s database regime only provides protection for foreigners on a reciprocal basis, similar proposals have been before the US congress for a number of years (for example, the draft Database Investment and Intellectual Property Anti-Piracy Act of 1996). The EU and the US also tabled proposals for an international treaty on database protection at the 1996 WIPO Diplomatic Conference.
Box 5.2 IP Protection of databases
IP protection of databases is a
very important issue for science, research, innovation and creativity, given
the global proliferation of computerised information services. Advances in
information and communication technologies have made digital databases of
factual information an essential resource for accelerating the growth of
knowledge and for producing new discoveries. And the expansion of the Internet
facilitates their wide dissemination and easy use. At the same time, the same
technologies make unauthorised uses and wholesale misappropriation of these
valuable databases relatively simple. The central issue here is, on the one
hand, the balance between addressing concerns of database creators regarding
the provision of incentives and protecting investment in new database products
and services and, on the other, safeguarding customary access to the data they
contain by users from the scientific, education and library communities.
In most countries, databases
qualify for IP protection through trademark and copyright legislation (they may
also be protected de facto through contracts between the users of the database
and the service provider). However, protection for databases under copyright
law is limited. The Berne Convention protects compilations or collections of
works but is silent on the protection of collections of material other than
works that are themselves copyrightable. In the famous 1991 case of Feist Publications Inc. v. Rural Telephone
Service Co., the US Supreme Court denied protection to a telephone
directory on the grounds that the collecting of names, addresses and telephone
numbers was not an original creative work.
Under the EU’s sui generis regime, introduced in 1996, database creators have the
right to prevent extraction of the whole or a substantial part of the contents
of the database for a period of 15 years, although this term of protection is
renewable whenever substantial change is made (for example, through adding more
data). The argument that the EU’s regime is designed to protect investment
rather than original creative expression is supported by the fact that in order
to gain protection, the creators need only show that they have made a
“substantial investment” in developing the database.
Digitalisation and the potential for instant, low-cost global communication have opened tremendous new opportunities for the dissemination and use of scientific and technical databases in developing countries, as elsewhere in the world. Indeed, the ability to access existing databases and to extract and recombine selected portions of them for research has become a key part of the scientific process. However, commercially-owned private sector databases typically seek to control unauthorised access in order to maximise revenues from subscriptions, even when some of the data they contain may be in the public domain or collected through publicly funded research. Our central concern here, therefore, is that a strengthening of IP protection for databases at the international level, whilst encouraging more investment in new commercial database products and services, may at the same time greatly reduce the access of scientists and researchers in developing countries to the data they contain because they will often lack the financial means to pay for the necessary subscriptions.
It is clear that the issues surrounding access to information and knowledge over the Internet are still emerging. In some respects, they are of limited immediate importance in many developing countries, given these nations’ limited Internet connectivity. However, Internet issues are crucial to universities and scientific research in the developing world, and may soon be central to secondary and even primary education in developing nations since Internet access will be much less expensive than the construction and stocking of libraries. The Internet has remarkable potential for development and it is imperative that this is not lost.
More analysis needs to be undertaken about the best means of protecting digital content and the interests of rightsholders, whilst at the same time honouring principles that ensure adequate access and “fair use” for consumers. More specifically, policymakers need to gain a better understanding of the impacts of the trend towards on-line distribution and technological protection of content on developing countries. There is a possibility that much such material will be protected technologically or through contractual provisions that are imposed as a condition of accessing the material. And it is not clear how reasonable requirements of “fair use” will be guaranteed in such an environment.
Bearing in mind this considerable level of uncertainty, we conclude that it is premature at the present time for developing countries to be required to go beyond TRIPS standards in this area. We believe developing countries would probably be unwise to endorse the WIPO Copyright Treaty, unless they have very specific reasons for doing so, and should retain their freedom to legislate on technological measures. It follows that developing countries, or indeed other developed countries, should not follow the example of the DMCA in forbidding all circumvention of technological protection. In particular, we take the view that legislation such as the DMCA shifts the balance too far in favour of producers of copyright material at the expense of the historic rights of users. Its replication globally could be very harmful to the interests of developing countries in accessing information and knowledge they require for their development. Similarly we have concluded that the EU Database Directive goes too far in providing protection for assemblages of material and will restrict unduly access to scientific databases required by developing countries.
Users of information available on the Internet in the developing nations should be entitled to “fair use” rights such as making and distributing printed copies from electronic sources in reasonable numbers for educational and research purposes, and using reasonable excerpts in commentary and criticism. Where suppliers of digital information or software attempt to restrict “fair use” rights by contract provisions associated with the distribution of digital material, the relevant contract provision may be treated as void. Where the same restriction is attempted through technological means, measures to defeat the technological means of protection in such circumstances should not be regarded as illegal. Developing countries should think very carefully before joining the WIPO Copyright Treaty and other countries should not follow the lead of the US and the EU by implementing legislation on the lines of the DMCA or the Database Directive.
INTRODUCTION
In its original “modern” conception the patent system was, in the words of the American Constitution, “to promote the Progress of Science and useful Arts, by securing for limited Times to Authors and Inventors the exclusive Right to their respective Writings and Discoveries”. The purpose was to stimulate invention, by rewarding inventors with a right to exclude others from the use of their invention, where the reward should relate to the usefulness of the invention to society. The disclosure of information in the patent was also seen as stimulating technical progress.
Over time, the emphasis has shifted towards viewing the patent system as a means of generating the resources required to finance R&D and to protect investments. Since the patent system offers a standard level of protection in all the fields it covers, there can be no direct link between the value of the right granted for a particular invention and the costs incurred in R&D. There may be a link between the value of the monopoly and its social utility, if the demand in the market is taken as a reliable indicator of the latter. But, for developing countries in particular, this is far from being the case. The patent system cannot stimulate inventions that are useful to society if the potential beneficiaries cannot pay for them, or someone else is not prepared to pay on their behalf.
As we noted in the Overview, there are concerns about the way the system has evolved which apply to developed countries as well as developing countries. These relate in particular to the application of the patent system to the new generation of technologies, particularly in the life sciences and information technology. The development of biotechnology has been accompanied by the more widespread patenting of living things, whose patentability was confirmed in the US by the Supreme Court case of Diamond versus Chakrabarty in 1980.[304] S[D1]imilarly the development and growing sophistication of information and communications technology has been accompanied by the extension of patenting to computer software in the US.
This extension to new technologies, has been accompanied by greater use of the patent system. In the US, and to a lesser extent worldwide, the number of patents granted has been rapidly rising. Between 1981 and 2001, the number of patents granted in the US has increased from 71000 to over 184000, an increase of 159%. In the last five years the rise has accelerated, the number of patents granted has increased by over 50%, compared to an increase of under 14% in the previous five years. This increase appears to reflect growth in the intensity of patenting (for example, per dollar spent on research), rather than a 50% increase in the number of inventions. In the 1990s, US R&D expenditures increased in real terms by nearly 41%, while patents granted rose by over 72% in the decade to 2001.[305]
The patent system is designed as a tool to provide an incentive to technical progress. The effectiveness with which it can do this will depend on the fit between the nature of the incentive and the processes by which technological development takes place. But whereas the patent system has uniform criteria to judge patent applications, the pattern of technical progress may vary significantly in different fields. The patent system fits best a model of progress where the patented product, which can be developed for sale to consumers, is the discrete outcome of a linear research process. The safety razor and the ballpoint pen are examples, and new drugs also share some of these characteristics.
By contrast in many industries, and in particular those that are knowledge-based, the process of innovation may be cumulative, and iterative, drawing on a range of prior inventions invented independently, and feeding into further independent research processes by others.[306] Knowledge evolves through the application of many minds, building often incrementally on the work of others. Sir Isaac Newton modestly wrote a long time ago: “If I have seen further it is by standing on the shoulders of giants”.[307] Moreover much research consists of the relatively routine development of existing technologies. For instance, gene sequencing, formerly a labour intensive manual technique, is now a fully automated process, involving little creativity. The development of software is very much a case of building incrementally on what exists already. Indeed, the Open Source Software Movement depends precisely on this characteristic to involve a network of independent programmers in iterative software development on the basis of returning the improved product to the common pool.
In practice, it is often difficult to distinguish between “discrete” and “incremental” or “cumulative” research processes, because research is carried out in so many ways and there is often a serendipitous element. But for the most part, the “cumulative” model now seems to fit more research than the “discrete” model. A patent system, which evolved with the latter concept in mind, may not be optimal for the former. Thus, as Merges and Nelson point out:
“Ultimately it is important to bear in mind
that every potential inventor is also a potential infringer. Thus a
"strengthening" of property rights will not always increase
incentives to invent; it may do so for some pioneers, but it will also greatly
increase an improver's chances of becoming enmeshed in litigation… When a broad patent is granted…its scope
diminishes incentives for others to stay in the invention game, compared again
with a patent whose claims are trimmed more closely to the inventor's actual
results. This would not be undesirable if the evidence indicated that control
of subsequent developments by one party made subsequent inventive effort more
effective. But the evidence, we think, points the other way.”[308]
The crucial issue here is the extent to which the patent system as it has now evolved in the developed world, and which the developing world is being pressed to adopt, will provide appropriate incentives for invention. One of the fundamental dilemmas here is the large number of patents on technologies that may be outputs of one research process, but are possible inputs into one or several downstream processes. One example is the issue of patenting “research tools.”[309]
In concert with the expansion of patenting in the private sector, public research institutions have been accelerating the transfer of the technologies that they develop by patenting. In the US, this approach was encouraged by the introduction of the Bayh-Dole Act in 1980, and the policy has since spread to other developed countries and, increasingly, to the more technologically advanced developing countries. Patents awarded annually to US universities have increased nearly tenfold, from less than 350 in the 1970s to over 3000 in 2000. The share of patents granted to academics in the US has increased from 0.5% to 2% of the total over the same period.[310] This policy, according to some, has stimulated a flow of inventions from universities and promoted their commercialisation, to the wider economic benefit of society. For others, it raises concerns about the possible restriction of access to research findings or their utilisation by others; the possible distortion of research priorities in the public sector, and as to whether the increase in patenting is a valid indicator of the acceleration of technology transfer. We consider what these concerns about the patent system in developed countries mean for developing countries.
First, in order to avoid the possibility of encountering similar problems to the developed world, developing countries should try to devise patent systems to take account of their particular economic and social circumstances. Both patent offices and legislatures in developing countries need be fully aware of the commercial and social impact of the approach they take in devising and implementing patent policy. The more technologically advanced developing countries may wish to adopt systems that provide extensive patent protection as incentives for R&D. On the other hand, they would also wish to avoid those aspects of the system which could provide disincentives to R&D, in particular follow-on innovation. They would wish to avoid resources being diverted to litigation and disputes about patents of doubtful validity, and rent-seeking[311] behaviour amongst rights holders of doubtful social benefit. Such systems would need to have adequate safeguards to ensure a competitive environment, and to minimise costs for consumers. Because much of the scientific and technological expertise in developing countries is concentrated in the public sector, there will need to be careful consideration of the implications of patenting by research institutions and universities. Countries which have a weak scientific and technological infrastructure will have less reason to adopt extensive patent protection, given that most of their technology is imported.
Secondly, a very difficult issue concerns how the interests of developing countries should be reconciled with the current pressures to harmonise the international patent system with the standards of the developed countries. This issue is raised by both the increase in the number of patent applications which is imposing heavy demands on the resources of many patent offices, and the recognition that there is considerable duplication of effort in the system, particularly with regard to the need to submit multiple applications for a single invention in different jurisdictions. Such duplication could be avoided by harmonising differences in standards and criteria in search and examination procedures. For some, the ultimate goal is an international patent, valid throughout the world and based on a single application process. But if, as we argue, developing countries should be encouraged to devise patent systems that suit their individual circumstances and objectives, which themselves will vary according to their stage of development, how should developing countries then proceed?
The crucial questions for developing countries which arise from the discussion above are:
· How should developing countries frame their patent legislation and practice? What measures can developing countries adopt in general to minimize the possible adverse effects of patenting regimes?
· Should developing countries encourage their public sector research institutions to patent their inventions?
· To what extent does the patent system inhibit research relevant to developing countries? Is the patenting of research tools a problem for developing countries?
· What would be the optimal approach for developing countries to take in relation to patent harmonisation?
Introduction
We believe that in considering the design of their patent systems, developing countries should adopt a pro-competitive strategy that, as one observer suggests, is tilted towards second comers rather than distant patentees.[312] This is especially important in those areas of technology such as pharmaceuticals and agriculture where, as we have already considered, the cost of providing strong protection is likely to be greatest. Such a pro-competitive strategy is best realised by seeking to restrict the scope of patent protection provided.
This
should be achieved, within the constraints of international and bilateral
obligations, by:
·
limiting the scope of subject matter that can be patented
·
applying standards such that only patents which meet strict
requirements for patentability are granted and that the breadth of each patent
is commensurate with the inventive contribution and the disclosure made
·
facilitating competition by restricting the ability of the patentees
to prohibit others from building on or
designing around patented inventions
·
providing extensive safeguards to ensure that patent rights are not
exploited inappropriately
·
considering the suitability of other forms of protection to encourage
local innovation.
We consider below how these objectives can be put into practice.
Historically, as we have seen, countries have adapted their patent regimes to encourage, discourage or more often prohibit patents in certain areas of technology. The advent of TRIPS, with its requirement for a more consistent approach to different fields of technology,[313] has reduced the options available to patent legislators. Nevertheless drafters of patent legislation still have a significant array of tools, even if some of them have been blunted by TRIPS. Numerous books and texts detailing the range of options available under TRIPS have been produced.[314] In the following paragraphs we describe some of these options and consider their relevance to the type of pro-competitive patent regime that we recommend for the majority of developing countries. We also consider how some of the recommendations relating to patent policy made in the preceding chapters on health and agriculture can be implemented.
TRIPS requires that “patents shall be available for any inventions, whether products or processes, in all fields of technology provided they are new, involve an inventive step (non obvious) and are capable of industrial application (useful)”[315]. It does not however define the term “invention”, nor does it prescribe how the three criteria for patentability are to be defined. Indeed we would note that it is not uncommon for different courts in Europe, even when applying identical law, to come to different conclusions on whether a patent is or is not obvious. There is therefore ample scope for developing countries to determine for themselves how strictly the common standards under TRIPS should be applied and how the evidential burden should be allocated.
Developed and developing countries have historically provided that certain things do not constitute inventions for the purpose of patent protection. Included in these are those set out, for example, in Article 52 of the European Patent Convention (EPC):
a) discoveries, scientific theories and mathematical methods;
b) aesthetic creations;
c) schemes, rules and methods for performing mental acts, playing games or doing business, and programmes for computers;
d) presentations of information.
Article 52(4) of the EPC also provides that methods for treatment of the human or animal body by surgery or therapy and diagnostic methods practised on the human or animal body shall not be regarded as inventions which are susceptible of industrial application. Article 53(b) of the EPC provides that patents shall not be granted for plant or animal varieties or essentially biological processes for the production of plants and animals
Even though subsequent EPO practice and jurisprudence have to some extent diluted the scope of these Articles,[316] it would seem entirely reasonable for most developing countries to adopt this list of exclusions as a minimum. Indeed we have already gone further by concluding in Chapter 3 that developing countries should not generally make patent protection available for all plants and animals.[317] A number of developing countries have also sought to limit further what constitutes a patentable invention. For example, the Common Industrial Property Regime of the Andean Pact countries provides that the following shall not be considered as inventions:
“Any living thing, either complete or
partial, as found in nature, natural biological processes, and biological
material, as existing in nature, or able to be separated, including the genome
or germ plasm of any living thing.”[318]
Similar provisions can be found in the legislation of Brazil and Argentina. We consider further below the question of what rules should apply to the patentability of genetic material.
The debate surrounding patent protection for certain inventions particularly those covering biological material is clearly about more than economics. For a significant number of people, in both developed and developing countries, the idea of patenting living organisms is morally wrong. This is often associated with the view that living things should not be patented because they can, by definition, only be discovered, not invented. In recent discussions within Europe on the protection to be afforded to biotechnological inventions, groups opposing patents on “life” were actively involved.[319] The final text of the resulting EC Directive[320] made some provision for excluding certain groups of inventions[321] from patent protection on moral grounds but it still allowed patents on plants and animals and genetic material. A similar debate in a developing country where domestic economic interests favouring patents on living things are likely to be weaker and where cultural and religious values often differ, might lead to a different outcome. In such a case a decision to deny patents on ethical grounds might be made for inventions claiming genetic material such as human genes. However, an exclusion of this type would be sustainable on the basis of the morality exception of Article 27.2 of TRIPS only if the prevention of the “commercial exploitation” of the invention denied a patent is deemed necessary. It is therefore debatable whether the exclusion can be applied while at the same time permitting the sale or other commercial exploitation of the invention.
Some ethical concerns about gene-based technologies may extend only to the possibility of someone claiming a monopoly over the technology, rather than to its commercial exploitation. In which case seeking an exclusion from patent protection may best be achieved by a strict application of the criteria for patentability. These include, as we have discussed above, clearly defining what constitutes a patentable invention as opposed to an unpatentable discovery, and ensuring that the concepts of novelty, inventive step and industrial utility are properly applied. We recognise that, in practice, the distinction between a discovery and an invention can be difficult to define, and this is a continuing challenge to legislators.
Issues of morality may also arise in respect of patents other than those in the biotechnology field. For example, the UK and Kenya have recently decided to reject, on moral grounds, patents on landmines.
In Chapter 4 we
recommend that an absolute standard of novelty
be provided such that the prior art against which novelty is judged
includes disclosure through use anywhere in the world. Also, in Chapter 2, we caution against
developing countries simply taking over from the comparatively recent European
jurisprudence the counter-intuitive notion that a product may be regarded as
new, if a new use is identified for it. Such an approach is not required by
TRIPS and different views can reasonably be taken of whether it is desirable to
extend protection in this way, which developing countries will wish to consider
with care.
In certain jurisdictions, disclosure of an invention by the inventor in the
period, usually 12 months, preceding the filing of a patent for that invention
will not destroy the novelty of that patent. This grace period, which may be limited to disclosure only at
internationally recognised exhibitions or may cover any disclosure, is intended
to allow the patentee to seek backing or test the market for his
invention. However, in the absence of
any international harmonisation on grace periods, an inventor risks losing
patent rights in a jurisdiction not recognising grace periods because of
disclosure in one that does. For those
developing countries having few prospective patentees, there may therefore be
little to gain from providing a grace period.
At present an invention is typically considered to be inventive if it is not obvious to a person skilled in the art.[322] Some would argue that this standard as it is now applied, for example by the USPTO or the EPO, is too low resulting in a proliferation of patents for trivial inventions which may not contribute to the over-riding objective of the patent system which is the advancement of science for public benefit.
We are not
aware of any significantly higher standard being applied currently
elsewhere. However, there are examples
of higher standards being applied in the past.
For example, in the first half of the 20th Century, the US
applied a “flash of creative genius” standard which would probably render the
majority of patents currently issued invalid.
For developing countries, the currently prevalent low standard of inventive step raises two concerns. The first is that as applied in developed countries, it could hinder research of importance to developing countries. The second concern is that developing countries would be expected to apply a similar standard in their own regimes. We would urge developing countries to think carefully before doing so and to explore whether a different higher standard is more desirable. One suggestion that has been made would be to require the patent applicant to demonstrate that the proposed invention reflects a standard of inventiveness higher than that which is normal in the industry involved.[323] The objective of any standard should be to ensure that routine increments to knowledge, involving minimal creative input, should not generally be patentable.
Developing countries will need to consider the possible impact of any higher standard of inventive step on the ability of domestic enterprises to protect their own innovations. We return to this issue shortly when we consider the importance of second tiers of protection such as utility models.
The requirement that the invention has an industrial application (or utility in the US) is perhaps the only patentability requirement to have been made more stringent in recent times. This has arisen essentially because of the difficulty of determining whether certain biotechnology-related inventions such as those covering genes or proteins really have any industrial application. Often any such application is not evident from the invention itself. The USPTO has recently provided guidance on how utility should be assessed in cases involving DNA sequences.[324] In such cases, utility can be established only if the patent application discloses a specific, substantial and credible utility. Such a requirement is now to some extent also being applied by the EPO.[325] It is to be hoped that this new standard will prevent patents being granted on inventions for which only a speculative application is disclosed, but it may be that it does not go far enough and the impact of the new Guidelines will therefore need to be closely monitored.
Developing countries providing patent protection for biotechnological inventions [PT2]should assess whether they are effectively susceptible to industrial application, taking account of the USPTO guidelines as appropriate.
The contract with society for the granting of a patent is that a limited monopoly period will be awarded in return for which the applicant will fully disclose his invention. The extent of the disclosure considered necessary to satisfy the applicant’s part of the contract varies amongst countries. In some countries including the US, the applicant is required not only to fully disclose his invention in a manner that would enable another party to put it into practice, but must also disclose the best mode for doing so. The sanction for non-compliance is usually the loss of the patent.
Developing countries should adopt the best mode
provision to ensure that the patent applicant does not withhold information
that would be useful to third parties. [PT3]
A further issue relating to disclosure concerns the possible requirement to disclose the source of any biological material used in the invention which we discuss in Chapter 4.
The relationship between the extent of the disclosure and the scope or breadth of protection sought is another important issue. Patent regimes typically require that the invention be disclosed in the patent application in a manner sufficiently clear and complete for it to be carried out by a person skilled in the art. The claims made should also be supported by the description of the invention. The standard applied in the UK, for instance, is that a fair statement of claim is one which is not so broad that it goes beyond the invention nor yet so narrow as to deprive the patent applicant of a just reward for the disclosure of his invention.[326] The UK Courts have also recently stated that the disclosure must be sufficient to enable all aspects of the claimed invention to be performed, and the disclosure of a single manner of putting the invention into practice will not always be sufficient.[327]
But what is meant by a broad claim? Take the example of an inventor of a new compound for the treatment of headaches. She discloses the potential use for her compound in her patent application, but her claims extend beyond that use to the compound itself, and all its potential uses. During the life of the patent, someone else establishes that the compound is also useful in treating heart disease. Is it right that the patentee can then prevent the compound being used, without her authorisation, for purposes she had not foreseen? Are such broad claims really justified on the basis of limited disclosure?
Patent laws in developed countries have typically justified this type of broad claiming on the basis that the inventor has made available to others two things: the compound itself and the first use of it. Whilst the issue of the breadth of claims is a generic one, it arises particularly in relation to the patenting of genes. As noted above, some take the view that an isolated gene (even when one or more of its functions have been determined) should not be patentable because it pre-exists in nature and would constitute a discovery rather than an invention. However, if a country opts for allowing patents over genes, it is crucial to define the possible scope of protection. At present, if a researcher isolates a gene and is granted a patent, for example, for the use of that gene as a diagnostic for a particular disease, depending upon the precise wording of the claim and the approach that the local law takes to interpretation of the patent, she may be able to assert rights over all uses of that gene, including those as yet undiscovered. Given that the isolation and identification of a gene is now a more routine procedure since the human and other genomes have been sequenced, the researcher stands to gain a level of protection which is considerably greater than her contribution. Moreover, because it is difficult for others to ‘invent around’ a gene, the researcher may be able to exercise a powerful monopoly.
A recent report on DNA patents, after considering the issue in detail, suggested that “consideration be given to the concept of limiting the scope of product patents that assert rights over naturally-occurring DNA sequences to the uses referred to in the patent claims, where the grounds for inventiveness concern the use of the sequence only and not the derivation or elucidation of the sequence itself”.[328] This would lead to the researcher being awarded only the rights to the uses that he has set out in the specification, and not all uses.
This issue is as relevant to developing countries as it is to developed countries. Therefore we suggest that developing countries conduct their own investigation into ways of ensuring that the scope of patent claims in their own jurisdictions are consistent with the disclosure. Developing countries might also wish to press for consideration of this issue within WIPO, possibly as part of the ongoing discussions on greater patent harmonisation.
If developing countries allow patents over genes as
such, regulations or guidelines should provide that claims be limited to the
uses effectively disclosed in the patent specification, so as to encourage
further research and commercial application of any new uses of the gene.
But measures to address the issue about breadth, as noted, extend beyond gene patents and should encompass broad patents in all fields of technology. While TRIPS forbids discrimination in terms of fields of technology, it is also desirable from a more general perspective to ensure that broad claims do not unfairly hamper research and competition in any field.
Applying the Standards
We have so
far suggested that developing countries should consider adopting higher
standards of patentability than those currently provided in many developed
countries. But it is not sufficient
just to incorporate these standards in the legislation. It is necessary also to
apply them. In Chapter 7 we address the issues relating to capacity, such as the scarcity of qualified
personnel, which might constrain a developing country from implementing an
effective patent policy. We also
consider the type of measures, such as contracting out the examination of
patents, which might be used to address some of these problems. We also discuss the possibility of
re-registering patents granted elsewhere, although with such a solution it will
be necessary to ensure that sufficiently high standards are applied when
examining the patent.
Whatever type
of system is adopted, it might be appropriate for developing countries to
consider providing some form of low cost opposition or re-examination
procedure.[329] In Chapter 4 we highlight the value of such
procedures in overturning invalid patents covering known traditional
knowledge. The type of opposition or
re-examination procedure that a developing country might consider adopting
could be a hybrid of the types of system currently available in some developing
countries, the US and in Europe. For
example, a system that allows an opposition to be made before grant, and the
patent to be challenged at any point during the patent term through an administrative
type procedure on the basis of any question relating to patentability, might be
desirable.
When
undertaking the examination of patent applications, developing countries should
seriously consider requiring the applicant to disclose all relevant information
concerning other corresponding applications filed elsewhere for the invention.
Developing countries should also consider supplementing the judgement of patent
examiners by inviting other available experts to comment on patent
applications. In Brazil, applications
for pharmaceutical-related patents are passed for evaluation to the Ministry of
Health who may be in a better position to comment on, for example, the
inventiveness of the claimed invention.
Exceptions to Patent Rights
In Chapter 2, we recommend that developing countries introduce the so-called “Bolar exception” to patent rights to facilitate early entry of generic competition in the pharmaceutical field. We have also suggested that providing an international exhaustion regime (i.e. permitting parallel imports of patented products) may be beneficial for developing countries. Such exceptions are however not the only ones that developing countries should consider. Most European countries, for example, provide that certain acts, such as those done for private and non-commercial purposes or those relating to experimentation on the subject matter of the patent (including for commercial purposes) shall not be considered infringements of a patent. The intent behind these exceptions, which is equally relevant for developing countries, is to encourage further innovation by enabling others to build on or design around the patented invention.
A further exception that already exists in a few developing countries provides freedom to use patented inventions for teaching purposes. Justification for such an exception might come from the copyright field where “fair use” of copyrighted works for educational purposes is well established. Indeed with the growing encroachment of patents into areas previously the sole domain of copyright, for example computer programmes, the relevance of an educational exception in the patent field may increase.
We have so far considered the requirements to obtain a patent and possible limitations to the rights of the patentee. We now consider tools for ensuring that such rights are not used in an inappropriate manner. We consider many of these issues in some detail in Chapter 2, but supplement them here.
In cases in which it is considered that the patentee is acting in an inappropriate manner then governments can intervene to remedy the situation. Such intervention could emanate from the general competition regime, or from within the patent system itself. The possibility of governments using, or allowing other third parties to use, a patented invention without the consent of the patentee is well established in patent law, and in TRIPS, as we note in Chapter 2. TRIPS prescribes a number of conditions that must be met in cases of such “unauthorised” use, but it does not prescribe the grounds on which such use can be authorised. Developing countries can therefore develop their own grounds for authorising compulsory licensing, or other exceptions to the rights of patentees (such as Crown or Government Use in developed countries). In considering introducing or revising legislation, they could seek guidance from the patent laws in other countries. For example, the US has used compulsory licensing in more than 100 antitrust cases.[330] The UK provides that compulsory licences may be granted on the following grounds:
· that the demand for the patented product in the UK is not being met on reasonable terms
· that the exploitation in the UK of any other patented invention, which involves an important technical advance of considerable economic significance, is prevented or hindered
· that the establishment or development of commercial or industrial activities in the UK is unfairly prejudiced.
Of course developing countries are not obliged to follow what countries such as the UK have done. Other grounds already adopted by developing countries include “public interest” and failure by a third party to obtain a licence under reasonable terms.[331] Brazil and other countries[332] have provided or are considering providing that a compulsory licence can be granted in cases where the demand for the patented invention is being met essentially through importation. As we note in Chapter 1, this type of measure was used by developed countries in the 19th and 20th centuries to limit the potential damage to domestic industry from issuing patents to foreigners. Questions arise however about the compatibility of this measure with TRIPS which makes patent rights enjoyable without discrimination as to whether the product is imported or domestically produced.[333] Developed countries, including the UK, have generally removed this provision from their statutes on the basis of their own interpretation of the TRIPS Agreement.
Ideally the mere
possibility of having a compulsory licence issued should be enough to encourage
the patentee to alter his behaviour. We
note in Chapter 2 that this is only likely to be the case where the threat is a
credible one in terms of there being a potential licensee capable of supplying
the patented product economically at a lower price than the patentee.
[PT4]An extensive use of compulsory licensing in developing countries is unlikely given the procedural complexities of the system. We nevertheless believe that an effective and credible compulsory licence system, as we recommend in Chapter 2, is an essential part of any patent policy. This is especially so for countries lacking a coherent or effective general competition policy.
Disputes about Patent Ownership
During our visit to Kenya we were made aware of the controversy surrounding a patent relating to an HIV vaccine filed by the Medical Research Council (MRC) in the UK. In particular, there were concerns that the contribution made by researchers at the University of Nairobi towards the invention claimed in this patent had not been adequately recognised. Partly as a result of the public pressure surrounding this case, an agreement was reached whereby the MRC, the University of Nairobi and the International Aids Vaccine Initiative (IAVI) would jointly own this particular patent and any future patents involving this particular development.[334] In the absence of such an agreement, the researchers from Kenya would have had to consider instigating legal action to obtain any just entitlement that they had to the patent or to any benefits accruing from its possible exploitation.
Most, if not all, patent laws presume that the person filing the application for the patent is entitled to be granted a patent. For example, under UK patent law, an applicant who does not claim to be the inventor is required to state his entitlement to the patent. Patent offices do not as a rule make any attempt to question prima facie statements relating to entitlement or inventorship, although a third party may initiate a challenge both before and after a patent is granted. To succeed with a claim, the third party must show that he is either the inventor or co-inventor of the patented invention or that he has a right to it by virtue of an agreement or operation of law. The burden of proof almost invariably rests on the person making the claim.
It has been suggested that there may be some benefit to be gained by the introduction of a requirement for applicants to demonstrate how they have achieved an invention in cases where the route to the invention might not be immediately obvious (for instances in some cases claiming biological material).[335] Such a requirement, which appears to be allowable under TRIPS, differs from the current requirement to describe how to put the invention into practice.[336] Whilst a more proactive role in investigating issues of entitlement may place an additional burden on already overworked patent offices, we do nevertheless believe that this suggestion is worthy of further study.
Encouraging Domestic Innovation
Many of the suggestions that we have made in this chapter reflect the fact that nationals of low income developing countries file very few patent applications. This should not be taken to indicate that there is no innovative activity in these countries; the problem is rather that the current patent system does not provide a suitable means for protecting their efforts. One possible reason for this situation is that the types of inventions being made may not possess the necessary level of inventiveness. Another important reason is the complexity and cost of acquiring rights, especially in foreign markets and, above all, of enforcing such rights in courts.
Many countries, both developed and developing, have recognised the need to protect the inventions, which result from what might be termed a “sub-patentable” type of innovation, and have therefore introduced a second tier of patent-like protection. Such systems are usually referred to as utility model or petty patent systems.[337] In comparison with the normal patent system, utility model or petty patent systems typically require a lower level of inventive step, provide a shorter period of protection and, in not being subject to any substantive examination prior to grant, are cheaper to obtain.[338]
Such characteristics are intended to make the system more attractive to small and medium size enterprises (SMEs) which typically have neither the desire nor the capacity to use the normal patent system. The type of innovative activity in such organizations may be more focused on relatively small incremental improvements to existing products rather than the development of completely new products. Such improvements, whilst not necessarily having the level of inventiveness for normal patent protection, do nevertheless contribute to technological advancement and should be encouraged. They are most likely to be beneficial for products, such as mechanical products, of a type likely to be produced domestically. They certainly should not be used as a substitute for normal patents (where we are recommending a raising of standards).
Evidence on how successful utility model systems have been in encouraging innovation in developing countries is hard to find.[339] During our visit to Kenya we were advised that the level of interest amongst Kenyan companies in their recently introduced utility model system had been disappointingly low. In other developing countries this is also the case. Figures compiled by WIPO show that in Argentina only 38 utility models were registered in 2000, and in Vietnam only 32.
Apart from those systems in current use, various other proposals have been suggested to encourage sub-patentable or incremental innovation. One of these is based on the provision of a right to a small royalty when the invention is used by others, but would not allow the prohibition of that use. This approach seeks to provide a reward for innovation, while reducing effects which might discourage follow-on innovation. But the administrative and enforcement requirements of such a system need to be tested to assess its practicality in developing countries.[340]
Rather than diluting the patentability standards to
capture the incremental type of innovations that predominate in many developing
countries, lawmakers and policy makers in these countries should consider the
establishment of utility model protection for stimulating and rewarding such
innovations. Further research would
seem desirable to assess the precise role that utility model protection, or
other systems with similar objectives, might play in developing countries.
A further type of protection is available in some countries[341] to allow a patentee to obtain protection for improvements that he makes to his own invention. These improvement patents or certificates of addition which typically expire at the same time as the patent on the initial invention, are intended to cover improvements that do not possess the necessary level of inventiveness that would allow them to be the subject of a separate independent application. The legal uncertainty that might arise if a patentee is allowed to extend the effective scope of his protection at any point in the life of the patent may deter other inventors from building on or designing around the patented invention. A patent system providing such improvement patents in parallel with a relatively high level of inventive step could however possibly prevent the unjust extension of the duration of patent protection that sometimes results when separate patents for relatively minor improvements are allowed.
In summary, we set out here, including recommendations from other chapters, the elements of a pro-competitive model of patent law which developing countries may consider. These are summarised in Box 6.1.
Box
6.1 Summary of Recommendations Relating to the Patent System
Developing Countries*
·
Exclude totally from patentability diagnostic, therapeutic and
surgical methods for the treatment of humans and animals
·
Exclude from patentability plants and animals and adopt a restrictive
definition of microorganisms
·
Exclude from patentability computer programs and business methods
·
Avoid patenting of new uses of known products
·
Avoid using the patent system to protect plant varieties and where
possible, genetic material.
·
Provide for international exhaustion of patent rights
·
Provide an effective compulsory licensing system and adequate
government use provisions
·
Provide broadest possible exceptions to patent rights including
adequate research exemption exception and an explicit “Bolar exception”
·
Apply strict standards of novelty, inventive step and industrial
application or utility (consider higher standards than currently applied in
developed countries)
·
Make use of strict patentability and disclosure requirements to prevent
unduly broad claims in patent applications
·
Provide a relatively low cost opposition or re-examination procedure
·
Provide means to prevent the granting or enforcement of patents
comprising biological material or associated traditional knowledge obtained in
contravention of access legislation or the provisions of the CBD
·
Consider providing alternative forms of protection to encourage
sub-patentable type local innovation.
Developed and Developing
Countries
·
Apply an absolute standard of novelty such that any disclosure anywhere
in the world can be considered prior art
·
Take greater account of traditional knowledge when examining patent
applications
·
Provide for the obligatory disclosure of information in the patent
application of the geographical source of biological materials from which the
invention is derived.
Least Developed Countries
·
Delay
providing protection for pharmaceutical products until at least 2016. Those who
currently provide protection for such products should seriously consider
amending their legislation.
*These recommendations are
considered relevant for the majority of developing countries. For those
developing countries seeking to promote certain sectors of technology then a
more selective approach may be desirable.
THE USE OF THE PATENT SYSTEM IN PUBLIC SECTOR RESEARCH
Introduction
A major change in the developed world has been the encouragement of patenting in state-funded research institutions or universities. The Bayh-Dole Act in the US permitted universities to patent inventions based on federally funded research on the premise that this would facilitate the commercialisation of research, and hasten innovation. Subsequently, most of the developed world has pursued similar policies. In the more technologically advanced developing countries there is also considerable evidence of such patenting activity. In some developing countries international applications for patents (through the PCT) come increasingly from universities or spin-off companies. For example, in China in 2000, universities and scientific research institutes accounted for 13.2% of domestic patent applications.[342] And in May 2002, China announced that research institutes were to be encouraged to file patents relating to government-sponsored research.[343] In 2001, India’s principal scientific organisation, the Council of Scientific and Industrial Research was the second largest PCT applicant from developing country institutions. Of the top 30 applicants from developing countries to the PCT, eight were from university or public sector research institutes.[344]
The theory underlying these policies is that patenting by public sector institutions and exclusive (or limited) licensing of technologies to the private sector increases the rate of commercial application of knowledge. Unless companies negotiate exclusive access to such technologies, it is argued, they would not have the incentive to invest the resources necessary to develop the technology into a marketable product. The opposing point of view contends that the interests of technology transfer and commercial application would be best served by the widest possible dissemination of knowledge through publication.
It is not really possible to say that either view is wholly wrong or right. Much depends on the individual situation. Traditionally, “basic” science was viewed as the main activity of the public/university sector and “applied” science the activity of the private sector. In the former, the incentives for scientific advance are the established systems of open disclosure, publication, peer review and promotion, and prestige associated with being first to make a discovery. In the latter the incentives and reward systems are commercial and financial, mediated by different forms of intellectual property protection. There was a symbiotic and finely balanced relationship between these two systems.[345] The university sector provided not only the scholarship to advance the progress of science but also the skilled people required by the private sector.
In the modern era, innovation has come to be seen as a more complex and interactive process. Throwing knowledge over university walls and hoping for the best is not now perceived as sufficient to encourage the application of that knowledge for economic and social benefit. Hence, the introduction of patents was seen as a means of changing the incentive structure in the public sector to address this deficiency. There has also been an erosion of the division, never very distinct, between basic and applied science. The development of biotechnology has resulted in some areas of basic science, such as genomics, being perceived as having potentially large commercial value. The combination of these two factors has resulted, particularly in the US, in a rapid increase in patenting by universities, particularly in the biomedical field.
Evidence
from the United States
So far, evidence from the US on the impact of the Bayh-Dole Act on technology transfer is inconclusive. Although, as noted, there has been a rapid expansion of patenting by universities, this alone does not demonstrate that commercialisation of inventions has increased. There is no firm evidence to indicate that researchers in US universities are producing more or better inventions than they would have done in the absence of Bayh-Dole or, if that is the case, that more of these inventions are being commercialised and applied. Supporters of Bayh-Dole point to the undeniable increase not just in patenting, but also licensing income and the number of start-up companies spun off from universities. In 2000 it was estimated that the gross royalty income for universities in the US amounted to $678 million, and that over 3000 start-up companies had been formed since 1980.[346] However, the increase in patenting and licensing activity can also be attributed to the growth of biotechnology, combined with the outcome of the Diamond versus Chakrabarty case, which would have contributed to an increase in patenting activity as universities conducted more research with commercial potential.[347] In addition, research funding, particularly from the NIH, greatly increased between 1980 and 2000. And R&D expenditure in US academic institutions rose by 150% in real terms between 1980 and 2000.[348] It is therefore difficult to determine the precise significance of the role of the Bayh-Dole Act in the expansion of patenting and, more importantly, whether or not it has increased technology transfer, and the application of technology, as compared to the counterfactual situation.
In the public sector, patenting and licensing activity can also provide both incentives and disincentives to the application of technologies. The incentive for commercialisation is predicated on the conferring of an exclusive licence to a commercial partner, on the basis that the exclusion of others provides the necessary incentive to the licensee to bear the risk of investing funds in development and commercialisation. But 50% of licences granted in the US in 2000 were non-exclusive.[349] To the extent that universities patent technology non-exclusively, there is arguably no technology transfer benefit because the numbers of those who can utilise the technology for further development is restricted by the licensing arrangement and the cost, as compared to simply publishing the results of research. But the incentive for further development and commercialisation, which is predicated on conferring an exclusive licence, is lost. Essentially, non-exclusive licensing is a tax on users of technology.[350] Exclusive licensing would appear to be important in developing early stage technologies which require considerable further development work. Against this, by its nature, the granting of an exclusive licence involves “picking winners”. In some documented cases, the licensee has failed to commercialise a technology, which other potential developers might have been better placed to exploit. Where a university develops a “ready to use” technology for which there is an obvious demand, then it can clearly earn income from patenting but, equally, there is no additional technology transfer benefit since the technology would have been taken up by the private sector anyway.[351]
For universities which create new products and processes, patenting can provide a useful source of additional income, although this has to be offset against the substantial costs of running a technology transfer office, as well as the costs of patent application and maintenance. For example, in 1999 the University of California (UC) received a gross income of $74 million from royalties and licence fees against gross expenses for the technology transfer office of $24 million. Of the $50 million “profit”, nearly $30 million was returned to inventors at the university, and the resulting balance used to finance university research.[352] Of course, UC is one of the foremost research universities in the world, and the average financial returns from patenting and licensing in the US are much lower. It is estimated that new research funding from licence income in US universities amounted to only $149 million in 1999, compared to total R&D expenditure in US academic institutions of $30 billion in 2000.[353]
Evidence
from Developing Countries
In the US, there is a dearth of evidence on how, if at all, patenting by universities affects research priorities. In developing countries, there is even less since patenting activity is at such a low level. Nevertheless, we consider that there is considerable potential for tensions to arise between the need to secure intellectual property protection for the products of research institutions and the achievement of their wider social objectives, particularly those relating to the needs of poor producers.
In the absence of much published evidence, we use as an example one of the leading agricultural research institutes in the developing world which we visited, as a means of illustrating the set of issues that developing countries will face in devising policies for the use of IP in publicly funded institutions. We were struck both by the vigour with which intellectual property protection was being introduced, and by the conscious effort being made to change the traditionally open culture of research. This change in policy envisages the protection of all assets produced by the Institute so that they can be licensed to earn revenue, or licensed free to small farmers participating in government programmes. While the institute’s guidelines state that this policy should be implemented without sacrificing its social mission, they also make clear that not seeking protection will be the exception rather than the rule, and any exceptions must be considered by its intellectual property committee. Underlying this change in policy is also a requirement from the government to meet 30% of the total costs of the institution from non-government sources. There is also a more or less explicit emphasis on improving the overall competitiveness of the commercial and export agriculture through cooperation with agribusiness. In particular, the development of transgenic crops is a crucial area because large multinational companies own much of the proprietary technology required.[354]
It is obviously too early to judge exactly how this policy, introduced only recently, is likely to affect research output and priorities. We note there is a conscious emphasis given to the policy providing financial benefits to researchers, and to the institute as a whole, to provide incentives. However, we think it is very important in introducing such a major change in research incentives and culture to ensure that the social mission of a research institute is not compromised. The rationale for the Bayh-Dole Act was to promote faster technology transfer and application, rather than raise funds for public institutions and researchers. If the primary motive is financial, then the government may be tempted to reduce funding on the grounds that an institute has the capacity to generate alternative sources of funding. Alternatively, governments could offer to match additional funding generated through the licensing of IP. Either way, there is a danger that research priorities will adjust to focus on the largest potential markets which, in this case, will be the commercial agricultural sector, to the possible detriment of poorer farmers.
Based
on the above, we believe that there is a role for IP in public research
institutions to promote the transfer and application of technologies. But it is important that:
·
generating alternative sources of funding is not seen as the
principal goal, which is rather to promote technology transfer.
·
care be taken to ensure that research priorities, particularly as
regards the technology requirements of the poor, be it in agriculture or
health, are not distorted by the search for a larger licensing income.
·
patenting and licensing should only be undertaken where it is judged
necessary to encourage private sector development and the application of
technologies.
·
careful consideration be given to the need to take out “defensive”
patents on important inventions, particularly for use as a bargaining tool
where complementary technologies are owned by private sector entities and
cross-licensing may be required to access those technologies.
·
expertise in IP is developed in public sector institutions which
traditionally have had none, but without losing sight of the objectives of
public policy for research.
HOW
THE PATENT SYSTEM MIGHT INHIBIT RESEARCH AND INNOVATION
The
Issues in Developed Countries
As the patent system has been applied to new fields of technology, we have seen that the primary issue is whether the balance between stimulating genuine invention of useful technologies, and protecting minor and intermediate technologies or processes that can hinder research by others can be attained. Many argue that the standards of patenting, particularly in the US, have been excessively lowered so that too many patents are issued for inventions that are trivial; or, because of pressures on patent examiners, too many patents are issued that will not prove valid in the courts if challenged.[355]
The problem in the US has been described thus:
“ …our patent system, while surely a spur to
innovation overall, is in danger of imposing an unnecessary drag on innovation
by enabling multiple rights owners to "tax" new products, processes
and even business methods. The vast number of patents currently being issued
creates a very real danger that a single product or service will infringe on
many patents. Worse yet, many patents
cover products or processes already being widely used when the patent issued,
making it harder for the companies actually building businesses and
manufacturing products to invent around these patents. Add in the fact that a
patentee can seek injunctive relief, i.e., can threaten to shut down the
operations of the infringing company, and the possibility for "hold
up" becomes all too real.”[356]
This may lead to behaviour by companies or public institutions that appears perverse from a social point of view. Organisations may patent in order to prevent others gaining access to areas of research, or to ensure that other organisations cannot block their research. They may also develop patent portfolios as a bargaining tool, with which to obtain access to technologies owned by other companies, through cross licensing. This is particularly a feature of small high technology companies. We note in Chapter 3 the importance of this kind of strategy in the agricultural biotechnology sector, and the extent to which it could result in costly patent disputes and litigation, and have possible implications for competition and concentration.
The problem was well put recently by an executive from CISCO in a submission to the US Federal Trade Commission:
“So obtaining patents has become for many people and companies an end
in itself, not to protect an investment in research and development, but to
generate revenue through licensing (“holding up”) other companies that actually
make and sell products without even being aware of their patents. They try to
patent things that other people or companies will unintentionally infringe and
then they wait for those companies to successfully bring products to the
marketplace. They place mines in the
minefield. The people and companies…who
file these patents and extract license fees from successful businesses play the
patent system like a lottery…The long delays in the patent office work to their
benefit by keeping the eventual coverage of their patents indefinite while
others produce products. They benefit
from the high cost of litigation by demanding license fees that are less than
the cost of litigation, hoping that people will pay even if they don’t
infringe, or, if they do infringe, it will be too costly to change the
product. This provides opportunities
for contingency fee litigators, for licensing companies and consulting firms
who claim to help people ‘mine’ their patent portfolios for patents that even
they didn’t know they had. It’s hard to
see how this contributes to the progress of science and the useful arts.”[357]
Of course, it is argued by some that this situation is a price that needs to be paid for the incentive effect of patents and that licensing strategies can be pursued to mitigate the most serious adverse effects. However, while there may be debate about the scale of the problem, and the degree of inhibition on research incentives, our principal concern is that developing countries avoid where possible the creation of similar problems in their own IPR regimes.
The problem of research tools applies both in the public and private sectors. Research tools have been defined as embracing “the full range of resources that scientists use in the laboratory, while recognizing that from other perspectives the same resources may be viewed as "end products."[358] In the public sector, these are seen as a problem particularly, for example, when one university wishes to access the patented technology of another for research, which some see as perverse when both are publicly funded. But this is a logical consequence of introducing patenting into the university arena. And the potential problem exists in all directions. Universities may wish to access private sector technologies, and vice versa. As we have seen, private sector companies may experience difficulties in accessing each others’ technologies which leads to a number of defensive strategies in an attempt to overcome them.
Recent research in the US suggests that, although there has been an increase in the patenting of research tools (such as gene sequences) required for drug discovery, it is not obvious that drug discovery has been substantially impeded.[359] Various strategies have been adopted to mitigate the potential problems. These include taking out licences on patents that may block research, inventing around patents, shifting to areas of research where there is more freedom to operate, moving research offshore, or simply infringing (or informally invoking a research exemption). Thus organisations have generally found a way around the problems. Nevertheless the transactions costs of undertaking research have been increased and delays incurred. Patents which prevent access need to be identified, negotiations held with relevant parties and licensing and legal costs incurred. However, adaptive changes have occurred in the institutional environment. As mentioned, the USPTO has issued new guidelines on patenting that raise the utility barrier for gene patents.[360] The NIH have also introduced new guidelines that are designed to mitigate problems in biomedical research.[361] The research referred to here concluded that, while there were social costs arising from research tools, these were unlikely to outweigh the positive incentive benefits from protection of research tools.[362]
The
Relevance to Developing Countries
Of course, this does not mean that it would not be desirable to reduce social costs arising from research tools if the benefits of the system are adversely affected. As we have noted above, developing countries can mitigate these problems by adopting an appropriate patent system, with limitations on the patenting of genes and appropriate exemptions for research. But this will not wholly address the problem. Much research relevant to developing countries may be carried out in developed countries, or in collaborative efforts with developed country researchers. In those circumstances, the rules applying in developed countries will be relevant.
While at the aggregate level the overall impact of patents on research tools may not be substantial, many research priorities relevant to developing countries are directed in relatively narrow fields of research where circumventing a problem created by research tools may be difficult. One example of this, which relates the general problem to that of developing countries is the patent on the CCR5 receptor that was subsequently identified as being important in transmission of the HIV/AIDS virus.
The US company Human Genome Sciences Inc. (HGS)
isolated the CCR5 gene during its sequencing of the human genome. The company searched databases for
homologues with known genetic sequences and concluded that they had found a
gene belonging to the family of cell receptors, and applied for a patent.
In February 2000, HGS was issued US patent No.
6,025,154 for “Polynucleotides Encoding Human G-Protein Chemokine Receptor
HDGNR10 (now called CCR5)”, which contained a broad claim covering the gene and
all medical applications, such as
therapies to block or enhance the receptor function.
Later, scientists from several academic centres
(including the Aaron Diamond AIDS Research Centre and the National Institutes
of Health) found that the CCR5 gene makes a receptor protein that the HIV virus
uses to gain access into an immune cell.
The receptor is a membrane-spanning molecule found on
the surface of cells in the immune system, binding them to the site of tissue
damage or disease. The HIV virus takes advantage of these receptors to bind and
gain access to the cell.
A certain CCR5 gene mutation, containing a 32-base
pair deletion, causes a shift in the reading frame of the bases in the DNA
sequence. This results in the receptor
protein being severely truncated and unable to reach the cell surface, thus
preventing the HIV virus from infecting the cells or slowing the rate of
infection.
Individuals with the CCR5 gene mutation are much less
vulnerable to HIV infection. The gene could be the means to identify a new
class of treatment for HIV/AIDS patients, such as a drug that could block the
receptor protein.
At the time when HGS isolated the CCR5 gene and
applied for its patent, the company was unaware that the receptor was one of
the entry points for the HIV virus into human cell. However, the broad scope of
the patent claims means that HGS have rights over any use of the gene, thus
enabling them to claim royalties through licensing contracts.
Although HGS has in fact already agreed to several
licences for the use of the CCR5 receptor gene in research into new drugs, the
example illustrates the possible dangers of granting patents on inventions
which are in reality little more than discoveries in which the use claimed is
merely speculative and based on an incomplete knowledge of the function of the
gene.
We have also considered in some depth a case involving the use of patented DNA sequences for research on malaria. The Malaria Vaccine Initiative (MVI) has identified a particular protein antigen (MSP-1) which may be crucial to the development of an effective vaccine for malaria. The ownership of patents relating to this protein was investigated, uncovering some surprising findings:
· The patenting of the DNA sequences for the antigen is very complex. There are up to 39 patent families that are potentially relevant in developing the vaccine from MSP-1.
· At the early stage of research on MSP-1, patents were granted on the basis of science that subsequent research found to be unsound.
· The citing of prior art in many patent applications appears incomplete, so that it is difficult to relate one patent to another.
· On that basis, a number of the patent claims made may be invalid (which is only verifiable through legal means or re-examination).